The Mysterious Establishment
excerpted from the book
Friendly Fascism
The New Face of Power in
America
by Bertram Gross
South End Press, 1980, paper
p54
American Heritage Dictionary
"Establishment: An exclusive group of powerful people who
rule a ) government or society by means of private agreements
or decisions."
The American Establishment is not an organization.
Nor is it a simple coalition or network. Like the industrial-military
complex, it has no chairman or executive committees.
(Like the Golden International,)the Establishment
is more complicated than any complex. It is a complex of complexes,
a far-flung network of power centers, including institutional
hierarchies. These are held together less by hierarchical control
and more by mutual interests, shared ideologies, and accepted
procedures for mediating their endless conflicts.
Like the establishments in other First
World countries, the American Establishment is not just a network
of State leaders. Nor is it merely a coalition of private governments.
It is an interweaving of two structures- polity and economy-that
under industrial capitalism have never been independent of each
other. It is the modern partnership of big business and big government.
As such, it is much looser and more flexible than the establishments
of classic fascism. And in contrast with them, above all, it operates
in part through-and is to an important extent constrained by-the
democratic machinery of constitutional government. Private agreements
and decisions-even well-protected secrecy-play a large role in
its operations; this adds to the Establishment's inherent mystery.
It is why people often refer to it as the "invisible government."
Yet many of its agreements and decisions are open to public view.
Indeed, so much information is available in public reports, congressional
hearings, and the specialized press that anyone trying to make
sense of it all runs the danger of being drowned in a sea of excessive
information. This, of course, is the problem faced by all intelligence
agencies, which usually feed on a diet of 95 percent public data
spiced with 5 percent obtained through espionage. Also, as with
intelligence and counterintelligence, there are huge information
gaps side by side with huge amounts of deliberately deceptive
misinformation.
p56
The number of people actively involved-even at the very top-is
too large for any meeting or convention hall. Robert Townsend,
who headed Avis before it was swallowed by IIT, has made this
estimate:
"America is run largely by and for
about 5,000 people who are actively supported by 50,000 beavers
eager to take their places. I arrive at this figure this way:
maybe 2,500 megacorporation executives, 500 politicians, lobbyists
and Congressional committee chairmen, 500 investment bankers,
500 partners in major accounting firms, 500 labor brokers. If
you don't like my figures, make up you own . . ."
I am convinced his figures are far too
small. If there are 4,000-6,000 at the top, they are probably
able to deploy at least five times as many in executive management;
who in turn operate through at least ten times as many junior
and contingent members. My total ranges between a quarter and
a third of a million. Even without adding their dependents, this
is a far cry from a small handful of people. Yet in relative numbers
this large number of people is still a "few." A third
of a million people numbers less than two tenths of one percent
of the U.S. population of about 220 million; and with their immediate
family members this would still be less than 10 percent. It is
less than one hundreth of 1 percent (.0001) of the "Free
World" under the shared leadership of the United / States.
Seldom, if ever, has such a small number of people done so much
to guide the destinies of so many over such vast expanses of the
planet.
There are conflicts at all levels. Most
of these are rooted in divergent or clashing interests, values,
perceptions, and traditions. Some are minor, others are major.
Many minor crises at various points in the Establishment are daily
occurrences, surprising only the uninitiated. But "whenever
we are prepared to talk about a deep political crisis," as
Papandreou observes, "we should assume that the Establishment
(as a whole) is undergoing a crisis, either because of internal
trouble-namely, because some of its members have seen fit to alter
their relative position within the coalition-or because of external
trouble, because another challenger has risen who wants a share
of the power." The bulk of these conflicts are resolved through
bargaining, accommodation, market competition, and government
decision making, particularly through bureaucratic channels. A
few more come to the surface through the legislative, judicial,
or electoral processes. Coherence is provided not only through
these procedures for conflict adjustment but also by large areas
of partially shared interests, values, and ideologies.
It is constantly changing. E the Establishment
were a mere defender of the status quo, it would be much weaker.
While some of its members may resist many changes or even want
to "turn the clock back," the dominant leaders know
that change is essential to preserve, let alone, expand, power.
"If we want things to stay as they are," the young nephew
said to his uncle, the prince, in Lampedusa's The Leopard, "things
have got to change. Do you understand?" Power holders may
not understand this at once, but events drive the point home to
them-or drive them out. Thus many of the changes occur in the
membership of the Establishment which, at any point, may expand
or contract. E the Establishment is a target, it is-in Leonard
Silk's apt words for the "overall corporate government complex"-a
"moving target." '
There is no single central conspiracy.
I agree with Karl Popper when he says: "Conspiracies occur,
it must be admitted. But the striking fact which, in spite of
their occurrence, disproves the conspiracy theory is that few
of these conspiracies are ultimately successful." Many of
them have consequences entirely or partly unintended or unforeseen.
Popper adds the observation that the successful ones rarely come
to public attention and that there is usually a "situational
logic" that transcends any conscious planning. When there
is a fire in an auditorium, people do not get together to plan
what to do. The logical response to the situation is "Get
out." Some will do it in an orderly fashion; others might
be rather rough toward people who get in their way. The Establishment
often operates this way. Some of its most historic achievements
have been forced on it by "fires" that break out suddenly,
often unanticipated. The major advances in the welfare state,
for example, have historical}y been opposed by most elements in
capitalist establishments who were usually too stupid or nearsighted
to realize that these measures would put a floor (or elevator)
under market demand, thereby promoting the accumulation of corporate
capital and taking the sting out of anticapitalist movements.
p59
The greatest difference between the Ultra-Rich and the rest of
us is that most of them are addicted to sensory gratification
on a grand scale. In part, as Ferdinand Lundberg has documented,
this gratification takes the form of palatial estates, fabulously
furnished town houses, private art collections, exclusive clubs,
summer and winter resort on many continents, membership in social
registers, birth and burial under distinctive conditions, etc.
It also involves an array of services going far beyond the ordinary
housekeepers, cooks, gardeners, masseurs, valets, chauffeurs,
yacht captains, and pilots of the large fleet of rich people's
private aircraft. But above all, the valets of the ultra-rich
also include expert executives, managers, advisers, braintrusters,
ghostwriters, entertainers, lawyers, accountants, and consultants.
Most of their services are more expensive (and far more sophisticated)
than those enjoyed by the emperors, emirs, and moguls of past
centuries. Some are freely given in exchange for the privilege
of approaching the throne and basking in the effulgent glory of
accumulated wealth. Most are paid for by others-either being written
off as tax deductions or appearing as expenses on accounts of
various corporations, banks, foundations, universities, research
institutes, or government agencies. These payments for modern
valet service can be unbelievably high. Indeed, one of the earmarks
of the Ultra-Rich in America is that they even have millionaires-most
of them involved in big business -working for them.
Among the Ultra-Rich, of course, there
are the so-called "beautiful people" who nourish their
addiction merely by using a little of what accrues to them from
fortunes managed by others. These are the "idle rich,"
the rentiers whose hardest work, beyond clipping coupons, is flitting
from one form of entertainment to another. There are also a few
deviants who betray their class by denouncing their addiction,
getting along with small doses only, ore actively using their
money to finance liberal or left wing causes. The great majority,
however, seem to be stalwart conservatives who abstain from idleness
by some form of "public service"-that is by holding
the most prestigious institutions of philanthropy, higher education,
health. culture. and art.
There are also those whose addiction is
more powerful; they can satisfy it only by larger and larger doses
of money or power. This can be done only by exercising directly
or indirectly their roles as overseers, roles legitimized by their
personal participation in the management of corporate property.
p62
Adam Smith
"Wherever there is great property, there is great inequality.
For one very rich man, there must be at least five hundred poor,
and the affluence of the few supposes the indigence of the many."
p63
C. Wright Mills
"No one can be truly powerful unless he has access to the
command of major institutions, for it is over these institutional
means of power that the truly powerful are, in the first instance,
truly powerful ..."
p63
Richard Barber
"Their [a few immense corporations] incredible absolute size
and commanding market positions make them the most exceptional
man-made creatures of the twentieth century.... In terms of the
size of their constituency, volume of receipts and expenditures,
effective power, and prestige, they are more akin to nation-states
than business enterprises of the classic variety."
p64
If better means more powerful, then the rich and the ultra-rich
are truly better than most people. While you and I may work for
major institutions, they are part of or close to (sometimes on
top of) the cliques that control them. Their family life is also
different. For ordinary people, family planning has something
to do with control over the number and spacing of children. For
the rich, family planning involves spawning trust funds and family
foundations that hide wealth and augment control of corporate
clusters and complexes. As a result of brilliant family planning,
the formal institutions of corporate bureaucracy and high finance
have not led to a withering away of the Morgans, Rockefellers,
Harrimans, du Ponts, Weyerhausers, Mellons, and other oligarchic
families of an earlier era. Nor have they prevented the rise of
newer family networks such as the Kennedys. Rather, the nature
of family wealth and operations has changed. "Rather than
an Irenee du Pont exercising absolute domination, now the [du
Pont] family fortune has been passed on to a number of heirs,
even as the family's total wealth continues to grow. This splitting
up of family stock blocks does not mean that capital no longer
tends to accumulate. Just the opposite . . . du Pont wealth, and
the power of their business class as a whole, is not diminishing,
but growing."
The growth of familial power, paradoxically,
has been made possible by the sharing of that power with nonfamily
members who handle their affairs professionally and mediate inevitable
intrafamily disputes. Many of the corporate institutions, moreover,
have been built and are guided by people who are merely rich and
are ultra-rich only in intent. Whether the heirs of old wealth
or the creators of new wealth, they mingle with the ultra-rich
in clubs and boardrooms and play an indispensable role in overseeing
corporate affairs.
The role of overseer no longer requires
total ownership-or even owning a majority of a company's stock.
Most corporations are controlled by only a small minority of corporate
stockholders. By usual Wall Street calculations, 5 percent stock
ownership is enough to give total control; in a few cases, the
figure may rise to 10 percent. The larger the number of stockholders,
the smaller this percentage. This "internal pyramiding"
is carried still further through chains of subsidiaries and holding
companies. Thus, strategic control of a small block of holding
company stock yields power over a vast network of accumulated
power and capital. Many of these networks include both financial
corporations and corporations in industry, utilities, communications,
distribution, and transportation. Most of the overseers are what
Herbert Gans called Unknowns. "How many
well-informed people," asks Robert
Heilbroner, "can name even one of the chief executive officers-with
the exception of Henry Ford II-of the top ten industrial companies:
General Motors, Standard Oil (N.J.), Ford, General Electric, Socony,
U.S. Steel, Chrysler, Texaco, Gulf, Western Electric? How many
can name the top figures in the ten top utilities or banks-perhaps
with the exception of David Rockefeller.''
While the names of chief executive officers
are a matter of public record, the names of the top stockholders
are not. Most wealthy individuals, as Richard Barber has shown,
"are tending to withdraw from direct stock ownership to companies
and to funnel their investments through institutions, especially
pension funds and mutual funds. This latter development has substantially
increased the power of institutions-pension funds, banks, insurance
companies and mutual funds-in the affairs of even the largest
corporations.
p90
As the takeoff toward a more perfect capitalism began after World
War II, popular support of the system was assured in large part
by the system's performance-more striking than ever before-in
providing material payoffs and physical security. The record of
over a third of a century has included the avoidance of mass depression
or runaway inflation in any advanced capitalist country, expanded
mass consumption, the maintenance or expansion of personal options,
no near-war between any advanced capitalist countries and, above
all, no world war.
Yet these achievements have depended upon
a level of commitment among the elites at the Establishment's
lower and middle levels that could scarcely have been forthcoming
if either had seriously doubted the legitimacy of the evolving
order. This legitimacy was fostered by a three-pronged ideological
thrust.
The first prong has consisted of a sophisticated
and passionate reiteration in a thousand variations of the simple
proposition: communism and socialism are bad.
Before World War II there were many small,
right-wing movements whose members were driven by nightmares of
evil conspirators-usually communists, Jews, Catholics, "niggers"
or "nigger lovers"-bent on destroying the "American
way of life." During the immediate prewar period, their fears
were expressed directly in the Dies Committee's crusade against
"pinkos" in the Roosevelt administration. After World
War II, these witch-hunting nightmares were transformed into dominant
ideology. Professional antiradicalism became entrenched during
the brief period of atomic monopoly. It grew stronger in the more
frenetic period of nuclear confrontation after Russia acquired
atomic bombs. With some toning down and fine tuning, it has maintained
itself during the present and more complex period of conflict
with socialism and communism. During each of these stages it meshed
rather well with anti-capitalist ideology in the Soviet Union,
China, Cuba, and other communist countries, thereby providing
an ideological balance to parallel the delicate balance of nuclear
terror. More specifically, it has given the overall rationale
for the extension of America's multicontinental frontiers. It
has helped link together the many disparate elements in America's
quasi-empire. In large measure, the unity of the NATO countries
in Europe had depended on their fear of Soviet communism, and
the allegiance of Japan to the United States on the fear of either
Soviet or Chinese communism. American aid to "have-not"
countries, in turn, has often varied with their ability to produce-or
invent-a communist threat on or within their borders. At home,
anti-communism has provided the justification needed by the ambitious
leaders of the massive military establishment. As Colonel James
A. Donovan wrote after retirement from the U.S. Marine Corps,
"If there were no Communist bloc . . ., the defense establishment
would have to invent one."
Above all, anti-communism has been a valuable
instrument in containing pressures for a more rapid expansion
of welfare-state measures as opposed to more generous forms of
aid to business. In this sense, the ideology of anti-communism
has also been anti-socialistic. Although favoring corporate and
military socialism for the benefit of businessmen and military
officers, the anti-communists have bitterly attacked the "creeping
socialism" that aims to benefit the poor, the underorganized,
and the ethnic minorities.
The power and the imaginative vigor of
anti-communist and antisocialist ideology has stemmed from its
many interlacing currents. At one extreme, there have been those
like Senator Joseph McCarthy and Robert Welch of the John Birch
Society, both of whom charged that Secretaries of State Dean Acheson
and George Marshall were communist agents or dupes. In the middle,
people like Acheson and Marshall themselves developed the more
influential, mainstream version of anticommunist ideology. By
deeds as well as words, they attempted to prove they were more
anti-communist than their detractors. Toward the left, many brilliant
intellectuals have done their own thing less stridently, demonstrating
the inefficiency of communist and socialist practice and the stodginess
of communist and socialist doctrine. Each of these currents have
been invigorated by significant numbers of former communists and
socialists, who have atoned for their former sins by capitalizing
on their special knowledge of communist inequity or socialist
futility. Each helped publicize many of the Soviet Union's hidden
horrors-although the tendency has been less to understand the
deformation of Soviet socialism (and its roots) and more to warn
against the horrors that would result from any tinkering with
the American system.
Thus, like a restaurant with a large and
varied menu, anti-communist and anti-socialist ideology has been
able to offer something for almost any taste. Each dish, moreover,
is extremely cheap. A high price is paid only by those who refuse
to select any variety, thus opening themselves to the charge of
being "soft on communism." For over a quarter of a century
there has been only a small minority-particularly in the realm
of government service and academia-willing to pay the price. The
result has been a rather widespread conformity with ritualistic
anti-communism and anti-socialism and a powerful consensus on
the virtues of the established order.
The second prong of the ideological thrust
consists of even more sophisticated variations on an equally simple
proposition: the capitalist order is good. Before World War II
one of the weakest links in the established order was the image
of the corporation. For its consumers, the corporation said, "The
public be damned!" On matters of broad public policy-particularly
during the depths of the Great Depression- corporate leaders often
distinguished themselves by ignorance and incompetence. There
was blatant evidence to support President Roosevelt's epithet
"economic bourbons." Even during the 1950s Charles Wilson,
a former General Motors president, as secretary of defense, was
able to suggest that what's good for General Motors is good for
the United States. In short, the large corporation-as the central
symbol of capitalism-was selfish, venal, and mean.
To cope with this situation, huge investments
were made in public relations campaigns. Some of these campaigns
concentrated on the corporate image. Many of them set forth in
excruciating detail the infinite blessings of private ownership
and free, competitive private enterprise. An exhaustive analysis
of the material appears in The American Business Creed, by a group
of Harvard economists. The essence of this so-called creed (to
which no serious corporate executives could possibly have given
credence) was the ridiculous assumption that the market was mainly
composed of small, powerless firms and that large, powerful corporations
were controlled by huge numbers of small stockholders instead
of a small minority of large stockholders, managers, or investment
institutions.
During the same period, however, a more
influential ideology for postwar capitalism was formulated by
various groups of pragmatic intellectuals. Their problem was that
many corporate managers and their truly conservative economists
were traditionally rather blunt in stating that their job was
moneymaking, period-no nonsense about social responsibility. Besides,
even the most dedicated corporate lawyers often remembered Justice
Oliver Wendell Holmes's dictum on the subject: "The notion
that a business is clothed with a public interest and has been
devoted to the public use is little more than a fiction intended
to beautify what is disagreeable to others." Nonetheless,
the Advertising Council spent billions over the decades in creating
fictional images of business "clothed with public interest."
In this they were helped by uninhibited academics like Carl Kaysen,
who stated that in the corporate world of Standard Oil, American
Telephone and Telegraph, Du Pont, General Electric, and General
Motors "there is no display of greed or graspiness: there
is no attempt to push off onto the workers or the community at
large part of the social costs of the enterprise. The modern Corporation
is a soulful corporation". Others have pursued the soulful
theme even further by suggesting that the executives of transnational
corporations are the real "world citizens" whose efforts
may soon usher in a new era of permanent peace.
The third prong in the ideological package
is the tacit-but breathtaking-assertion or premise that capitalism
no longer exists. "A research report of the United States
Information Agency," C. L. Sulzberger revealed in a typically
incisive column back in 1964, "has ruefully discovered that
the more our propaganda advertises the virtues of 'capitalism'
and attacks 'socialism' the less the world likes us . . . Most
foreigners don't regard 'capitalism' as descriptive of an efficient
economy or a safeguard of individual rights. To them it means
little concern for the poor, unfair distribution of wealth, and
undue influence of the rich." 37 But what the USIA allegedly
needed a research report to discover concerning capitalism's image
in other countries was already well understood by capitalism's
major publicists and spokesmen at home. As far back as 1941, in
his "American Century" editorial, Henry Luce used the
well-established term "free economic system" instead
of "capitalism." The international capitalist market
protected by American hegemony became the "free world"
and "freedom" became the code word for both domestic
capitalism and capitalist empire. In Carl Kaysen's article on
the soulful corporation, the nasty word "capitalism"
makes not a single entry. Its use would have introduced a jarring
note. It would also have violated a powerful norm among economists
namely, that instead of trying to analyze the workings of modern
capitalism, capitalism should be discussed mainly in the framework
of criticizing Marxian economics or making passing references
to the imperfections in Adam Smith's model of perfect competition.
When Governor George Romney of Michigan announced that "Americans
buried capitalism long ago, and moved on to consumerism,"
what was really being buried was the old-time conservative defense
of capitalism as unadulterated self-interest as superior to socialistic
altruism. True believers like Ayn Rand were of no avail in charging
that "if the 'conservatives' do not stand for capitalism,
they stand for and are nothing" and in proclaiming (like
one of her characters in Atlas Shrugged) "We choose to wear
the name 'Capitalism' printed on our foreheads boldly, as our
badge of nobility." The most intelligent spokesmen for the
changing capitalist order wear a variety of names on their foreheads.
The first term-and still the most appealing-has
been "mixed economy." The persuasive power of this concept
stems mainly from lip service to the perfect-competition model
as defined in classical or neoclassical ideologies. If capitalism
used to be what Adam Smith advocated, the reasoning goes, then
capitalism has been replaced by a mixture of private and public
enterprise-or even of capitalism and socialism. This mixture blends
the (alleged) productive efficiency of the former with the social
justice sought by the latter. At the same time, it preserves the
beautiful equilibrium of the classical model by providing opportunities
for all interests in society to organize in their own behalf.
From this competition in both the political and economic marketplaces
comes a peaceful resolution of conflicts through the negotiation,
bargaining, pressure and counter-pressure, propaganda and counterpropaganda
that underlie electoral campaigns and executive, legislative,
and judicial decision making. From this confused but peaceful
process of political competition among selfish interests there
emerges-as though by some invisible guiding hand-the best possible
satisfaction of the public interest. Granted, there may be some
imperfections in this political marketplace, too much strength
at some points and too much weakness at others. But then enlightened
government, with the help of Ivy League professors, can come in
as a balancing factor and restore the equilibrium.
This pluralistic myth is often reinforced
by statistical exercises suggesting that the unfair distribution
of wealth and influence was on its way out and the majority of
the population had attained "affluence." Thus the mere
contemplation of the "objective data" carefully selected
under his direction induced the usually self-contained Arthur
Burns (later named chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers
and the Federal Reserve Board) into the following orgasmic spasm
of economic hyperbole: "The transformation in the distribution
of our national income . . . may already be counted as one of
the great social revolutions in history." 30 With such well-certified
"evidence" coming across their desks, former Marxists
or revolutionaries were able to explain their conversion to the
existing order with something more convincing than diatribes (which
often appeared in the form of Trotskyism) against Stalinism and
more self-satisfying than the attacks on former comrades made
by the former communists who converted to professional anticommunism.
By 1960, Seymour Martin. Lipset was able to proclaim that "the
fundamental political problems of the industrial revolution have
been solved." 40 This viewpoint was enlarged by Daniel Bell's
sadly joyous funeral oration over the end of socialist or communist
ideology in the Western world: "For the radical intelligentsia,
the old ideologies have lost their 'truth' and their power to
persuade . . . there is a rough consensus among intellectuals
on political issues: the acceptance of the Welfare State; the
desirability of decentralized power; a system of mixed economy
and political pluralism. In that sense, too, the ideological age
has ended."
In continuation of the same argument,
Bell has moved to replace the old ideologies of competing systems
with a new end-of-ideology ideology, celebrating the new power
of theory, theoreticians, and his best friends. With more wit,
passion, and inventiveness than most competing sociologists, Bell
has capitalized on the fact that both Western capitalism and Russian
socialism have been forms of industrialism. In so doing he defines
industrialism loosely as something that has to do with machines,
almost completely glossing over the organizational and imperial
aspects of industrial capitalism.
This allows him to proclaim the coming
of something called "postindustrialism," which is characterized
by the increasing relative importance of services as contrasted
with goods, of white-collar employment, and of more technical
and professional elites. The essence of this allegedly "post"
industrialism is "the preeminence of the professional and
technical class." This preeminence, in turn, is based on
"the primacy of theoretical knowledge-the primacy of theory
over empiricism and the codification of knowledge into abstract
systems of symbols." The masters of the new theory and symbols
are the "knowledge elites" and their domicile is the
university, "the central institution of post-industrial society."
With equal wit and a larger audience,
Galbraith propounded a similar theme when, in 1968, he claimed
that power in the new industrial state has shifted from capital
to the "organized intelligence" of the managerial and
bureaucratic "technostructure."
For Bell, if the new knowledge elites
do not make the ultimate decisions, it is because of a combination
of old-fashioned politics and new cultural styles, particularly
among younger people who tend to revolt against the rule of reason
itself. If these obstacles can be overcome and if enough resources
are channeled into R & D and the universities, then man's
reason shall at last prevail and rational calculation and control
will lead to stable progress. For Galbraith, the remedy was similar,
since the system of industrial oligarchy "brings into existence,
to serve its intellectual and scientific needs, the community
that, hopefully, will reject its monopoly on social purpose."
Galbraith's hope lay (at that time) in the wistful presumption
that "the educational and scientific estate, with its allies
in the larger intellectual community" might operate as a
political force in its own right.
Although both Bell and Galbraith have
been willing to concede the existence of capitalism (and Galbraith
has more recently revealed himself as an advocate of public ownership
of the one thousand corporate giants whom he describes as the
"planning system," 44 most Establishment social scientists
in both the Ivy League and the minor leagues seem to have adopted
methodological premises that rule capitalism out of existence.
Without the wit, wisdom, or vision of a Bell or Galbraith, they
have busied themselves in efforts to provide technical solutions
to political, moral and socio-economic problems. 'The problems
they presume to solve-or in Daniel P. Moynihan's more modest terms,
to cope with-are defined at the higher or middle levels of the
Establishment where decisions are made on which research grants
or contracts are to be approved and which professors are to be
hired. They are carefully subdivided into categories that reflect
the division of labor within the foundations and government contracting
agencies.
In turn, the presumably independent "knowledge
elites" of the educational, scientific, and intellectual
estates-having usually abjured efforts to analyze the morality
and political economy of the so-called "market system"-are
now rated on their performance in the grant-contract market. The
badges of achievement are the research proposals accepted by the
Establishment, with the rank order determined by the amount of
funds obtained. Alongside the older motto "Publish or perish"
(which puts the fate of many younger people in the hands of establishment
faithfuls on editorial boards), has risen an additional imperative:
"Get a grant or contract and prosper." This imperative
also applies to department heads, deans, and college presidents
who-like professors-are expected to bring in the "soft money"
to supplement the "hard money" in the regular college
and university budgets. During the early 1960s the largest amounts
of "soft money," came from the government agencies involved
in the "hardware" and "software" needed by
the military and outer-space agencies, and including the many
programs of "area studies" focused on Asia, Africa,
the Middle East, and Latin America. Later, with the civil rights
and antiwar movements, a minor avalanche of "soft money"
was let loose for research, field work, and demonstration projects
in the so-called "anti-poverty" and "model cities"
programs. The word went quickly around among the new generation
of academic hustlers that "Poverty is where the money is."
Under these new circumstances, the serious applicant for funds
was well advised to steer clear of root causes or systemic analysis.
There was no prohibition against proposing research work or field
organization designed to challenge the capitalist system, but
no applicant has ever been known to openly propose anything so
patently "unsound." Moreover, many of the wisest heads
in the academic community-whether from profound inner disillusionment
or in the heat of professional arrogance-openly advocated the
treatment of symptoms only and inveighed against wasting time
with the examination of systemic roots of poverty, unemployment,
inflation, crime, or environmental degradation.
On a broader scale, methodology became
the "name of the game." A new generation of methodologists
learned that with unspoken constraints upon the purpose and content
of research and theory, greater importance must be attached to
means and form. Younger people who scorned the catch-as-catch-can
methodologies of a Bell, Galbraith, or Moynihan- and were embarrassed
by their unseemly interest in turning a good phrase -became the
new ideologues of scientific methods. On the one hand, "abstracted
empiricists" (as C. Wright Mills called them) became frenetic
data-chasers eager to produce reams of computer printouts. On
the other hand, enthusiastic model-builders erected pretty paradigms
from which hypotheses might be deduced. Both sought verification
through the application of methods long proven useful in the natural
sciences. In this process, they had the aid and participation
of many natural scientists perfectly willing to accept admiration
from those naive enough to think that their skills in physics,
biology, engineering or mathematics were readily transferable
to the analysis of social problems. They also enjoyed the guidance
or blessings of old-time radicals who-scorched by the heat of
the purges or disillusioned by Stalinism-were eager to build a
new God in the image of so-called scientific method. These activities
became intensely competitive, with ever-changing cliques and currents
providing endless opportunities for innovative nuances in the
production of iconoclastic conformity and irrelevant relevance.
Occasionally, the existence of capitalist
society has been allowed to enter into the frame of reference-but
only marginally. Thus, it has become fashionable for many social
science departments to have a well-behaved "Marxist"
in residence: an element of good behavior, of course, is to accept
the subdivision of mental labor and be a "Marxist" economist,
socialist, or political scientist rather than dealing with capitalist
society as a whole. A more widespread form of marginal acceptance
of capitalist reality is the idea of "putting the profit
motive to use in achieving social purposes." The reiteration
of this imperative in every area from narcotics control to education
has become one of the most effective methods of pledging allegiance
to the undescribed and unexamined capitalist order.
Although these many establishment ideologies
have not produced any dedicated loyalty or deep commitment to
modern capitalism, they have nonetheless been a major factor in
the purification process. They have made it possible for purges
and induced conversions of dissidents to be reduced in relative
significance and conducted on a low-key, routine basis. They have
helped absorb some of the activists of the old "New Left"
of the 1960s into the Establishment, purify thoughts and behavior
during the 1970s, and channel into harmless-if not profitable-ways
the resentments and grievances fed by the many crises and traumas
of a more perfect capitalism.
p153
During the so-called "Hundred Year Peace" (1815-1914),
all wars among the Great Powers were minor, short, or localized.
General peace was preserved in an environment of unending limited
war.
The period since 1945 has also been one
of limited war. Whatever military action has taken place-whether
in Korea, Indochina, the Middle East, Africa, or Latin America-has
been geographically limited. Although the devastation has been
ghastly, no nuclear weapons have been used.
But limited war has created a baffling
problem for the leading capitalist powers, particularly the United
States: A reduction in military stimulants to economic expansion
and capital accumulation. The present condition of the American
industrial establishment, writes David Bazelon, "is unthinkable
without the benefit of the capacity-building expenditures of the
past twenty years induced by war and preparedness measures."
The U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency has thought about
this in terms that are themselves unthinkable to most Establishment
economists: "It is generally agreed that the great expanded
public sector since World War II, resulting from heavy defense
expenditures, has provided additional protection against depression,
since this sector is not responsible to contraction in the private
sector and has provided a sort of buffer or balance wheel in the
economy."
Strangely enough, the use of military-growth
stimulants in the United States also served to stimulate growth
in the two major capitalist societies with relatively small military
budgets: Japan and West Germany. An important part of U.S. military
expenditures spilled over into both Japan and West Germany in
the form of both procurement of supplies and payments for the
maintenance of U.S. installments. More indirectly, the U.S. concentration
of war-related technology (which includes advanced computerization,
communication systems, and electronic controls) gave the largest
corporations in other leading countries of the "Free World,"
particularly Japan and West Germany, an opportunity to catch up
with, or plunge ahead of, the United States in civilian technologies
and thereby make spectacular advances in world trade.
As the United States began its slow withdrawal
from Indochina in 1969, military expenditures began to level off
and then-while prices for military goods were still rising-to
fall by almost $4 billion from 1969 to 1972. As a proportion of
total GNP, military spending fell even more drastically-from 9.1
percent in 1967 and 1968 to around 6 percent in 1979. Expenditures
for "international affairs" (closely related to military
expenditures) also declined. The size of the U.S. armed forces
fell from over 3.5 million in 1968 to 2.1 million in 1979. In
other words, the military slowdown under conditions of de-escalation
and détente deprived the American economy of a defense
against recession that had been provided during the 1960s. This
was one of the factors in the recessions that began in 1970, 1974,
and 1979. In each case unemployment rose. In 1975, the total end
to the hugely destructive war in Indochina was a retrogressive
economic force, as unemployment in the United States and other
capitalist countries rose to the highest levels since the Great
Depression.
The response of the industrial-military
portion of the Establishment has been prompt, publicly warning
against the great perils of becoming weaker than the communist
enemy and privately warning against the disastrous economic effects
of the slowdown. The positive action has been in two directions:
the expansion of new and costly weapons systems and the sale of
arms to other countries. Under conditions of détente, however,
the two of these together were insufficient to restore defense
spending to the proportions of GNP reached during Indochinese
wars. Thus the American industrial establishment was subjected
to a slow withdrawal of the stimulus to which it had become accustomed.
The NATO countries were subjected to a sharp decline in the vigor
of the Soviet "threat," which was the official raison
d'être for NATO's existence. The capitalist world was subjected
for a while to the "threat" of a peaceful coexistence
in which the economic stimulus of war and preparedness would no
longer be available at the level to which it had become accustomed.
With any decline in détente, of course, these conditions
change.
UNLIMITED OVERKILL
The dominant logic of "Free World"
militarism in a period of limited warfare has been slowly developing
during the 1970s. If unlimited warfare is "dysfunctional,"
then two lines of operation are indicated.
The first has been to channel a larger
portion of military resources into weapons systems produced by
the largest military contractors, even though this means a dwindling
number of people in the armed services. The result has been a
continuous increase in "overkill" capabilities whose
actual use would surely destroy capitalism itself, but whose production
and deployment contribute to the maintenance of a capital accumulation.
Overkill itself is matched by various forms of "overdelivery":
globe-circling missiles in addition to bombers; multiple warheads
on a single missile (MIRVs); launchings from roving submarines,
ocean-floor emplacements and eventually satellite space stations;
ocean explosions to produce tsunamis (tidal waves); antiballistic
missiles that would themselves emit vast radiation dosages over
the territory presumably defended; and, more recently, cruise
missiles that could be launched from submarines, planes, or ships,
fly at radar-eluding altitudes, and maneuver around defensive
fire. Less publicized, and often excluded from official estimates
of nuclear megatonnage, is the armory of "tactical"
nuclear weapons. These include huge numbers of air-to-ground,
ground-to-air, and ground-to-ground missiles, of which over seven-thousand
are stationed in Europe for use by NATO forces. The average yield
of these weapons, according to Robert McNamara as far back as
1964, was about 100 kilotons, about five times greater than the
strength of Hiroshima's Little Boy. Moreover, considerable "progress"
has been made in developing the biological, chemical, physiological,
and nuclear instrumentalities that could offer the prospect, in
the words of a high U.S. Navy official, of attaining "victory
without shattering cities, industries and other physical assets."
The extent of this progress was revealed by the announcement in
1977 of the "neutron bomb" and its promotion for NATO
use.
The second has been a massive escalation
of arms sales and government-subsidized arms gifts to Third World
countries. In the United States, this program-which represents
a huge stimulus to American industry-reached $11.2 billion in
fiscal year 1977, and then, under the Carter administration rose
to $13.5 billion in fiscal 1979. This activity has been paralleled
by similar arms exports from other "First World" countries.
A large part of these exports has gone to the Middle East, thereby
recycling "petrodollars" for such countries as Iran
and Saudi Arabia. A considerable part of the U.S. exports, in
contrast to those from most other First World countries, have
gone to Israel, as well as to Third World regimes threatened by
domestic upheaval.
Friendly
Fascism
Fascism watch
Index
of Website
Home Page