Building an Iron Cage
The Bretton Woods Institutions, the WTO, and
the South
by Walden Bello
excerpted from the book
Views from the South:
The effects of globalization
and the WTO on the Third World
edited by Sarah Anderson
Walden Bello is co-director of Focus on the Global South,
a Bangkok-based research, analysis, and advocacy program on North-South
issues connected with the Chulalongkorn University Social Research
Institute. A professor of sociology and public administration
at the University of the Philippines, he is author or co-author
of ten books, including Siamese Tragedy Development and Disintegration
in Modern Thailand (London Zed Press, 1998); Dark Victory The
United States, Structural Adjustment, and Global Poverty (London
Pluto Press, 1994); and Dragons in Distress Asia's Miracle Economies
in Crisis (London Penguin Books, 1991).
p55
Supporters of the World Trade Organization (WTO) often claim that
this multilateral institution protects weaker and poorer countries
from unilateral actions by the stronger ones by providing a set
of uniform rules and dispute settlement mechanisms for global
trade. Nevertheless, the WTO elicits fear, anger, and exasperation
throughout the global South, where it is widely believed that
this institution, rather than helping to level the playing field,
is deeply biased against the development of the South. This bias
was recently epitomized for many by the resistance of key northern
countries, led by the United States, to the appointment of Thai
Deputy Prime Minister Supachai Panitchpakdi as WTO director general.
This southern attitude toward the WTO can best be appreciated
if the emergence of the institution is placed in the context of
the South's struggle for development over the last 50 years. Situated
in this broad historical canvas, the Uruguay Round Agreement of
1994 emerges not so much as the triumph of enlightened free trade
over benighted protectionism but, more importantly, as the culminating
point of a campaign of global economic containment of the legitimate
aspirations to development on the part of Third World countries.
***
p65
THE 1980s AND EARLY l990s: RESUBORDINATION OF THE SOUTH
A. STRUCTURAL ADJUSTMENT
When the Reagan Administration came to power in 1981, it was
riding on what it considered a mandate not only to roll back communism
but also to discipline the Third World. What unfolded over the
next four years was a two-pronged strategy aimed, on the one hand,
at dismantling the system of "state-assisted capitalism"
that was seen as the domestic base for southern national capitalist
elites and, on the other, at drastically weakening the UN system
as a forum and instrument for the South's economic agenda. The
opportunity came none too soon in the form of the global debt
crisis that erupted in the summer of 1982, which drastically weakened
the capabilities of Southern governments in dealing with northern
states and corporations and northern-dominated multilateral agencies.
The instruments chosen for rolling back the South were the
World Bank and the IMF This was an interesting transformation
for the World Bank, which had previously been vilified by the
Wall Street Journal and the right wing as one of the villains
behind the weakening of the North's global position by "promoting
socialism" in the Third World via its loans to southern governments.
But the liberal McNamara, by that time faulted by the right for
losing Vietnam and failing to contain the southern challenge,
was replaced by a more pliable successor, and ideological right-wingers
seeking the closure of the Bank were restrained by pragmatic conservatives
who wished to use the Bank instead as a disciplinary mechanism.
"Structural adjustment" referred to a new lending
approach that had been formulated during McNamara's last years
at the Bank. Unlike the traditional World Bank project loan, a
structural adjustment loan was intended to push a program of "reform"
that would cut across the whole economy or a whole sector of the
economy. In the mid-l980s, IMF- and World Bank-imposed structural
adjustment became the vehicle for a program of freemarket liberalization
that was applied across the board to Third World economies suffering
major debt problems. Almost invariably, structural adjustment
programs (SAPs) had the following elements
* radically reducing government spending, ostensibly to control
inflation and reduce the demand for capital inflows from abroad,
a measure that in practice translated into cutting spending on
health, education, and welfare liberalizing imports and removing
restrictions on foreign investment, ostensibly to make local industry
more efficient by exposing them to foreign competition
* privatizing state enterprises and embarking on radical deregulation
in order to promote more efficient allocation and use of productive
resources by relying' on market mechanisms instead of government
decree
* devaluing the currency in order to make exports more competitive,
thus resulting in more dollars to service the foreign debt and
* cutting or constraining wages and eliminating or weakening
mechanisms like the minimum wage that protected labor, to remove
what were seen as artificial barriers to the mobility of local
and foreign capital.
By the late 1980s, more than seventy Third World countries
had submitted to IMF and World Bank programs, making stabilization,
structural adjustment, and shock therapy from distant Washington
the common conditions of the South. The main justification for
structural adjustment was to enable Third World countries to repay
their debts to northern banks. There was also a more strategic
objective, and that was to dismantle the system of state-assisted
capitalism that served as the domestic base for
the national capitalist elites. In 1988, a survey of SAPs
carried out by the UN Commission for Africa concluded that the
essence of SAPs was the "reduction/removal of direct state
intervention in the productive and redistributive sectors of the
economy." As for Latin America, one analyst noted that the
United States took advantage of "this period of financial
strain to insist that debtor countries remove the government from
the economy as the price of getting credit." Similarly, a
retrospective of the decade of adjustment published by the Inter-American
Development Bank in 1992 identified the removal of the state from
economic activity as the centerpiece of the ideological perspective
that guided the structural reforms of the 1980s. The book describes
the post-war period in Latin America as "the history of a
collective error in terms of the economic course chosen, and of
the design of the accompanying institutions" and proposed
the following remedy "the withdrawal of the producer state
and state-assisted capitalism, the limiting of the state's responsibilities
to its constitutional commitments, a return to the market for
the supply of goods and services, and the removal of the obstacles
to the emergence of an independent entrepreneurial class."
By the end of the twelve-year-long Reagan-Bush era in 1992,
the South had been transformed. From Argentina to Ghana, state
participation in the economy had been drastically curtailed; government
enterprises were passing into private hands in the name of efficiency,
protectionist barriers to northern imports were being radically
reduced; and, through export-first policies, the internal economy
was more tightly integrated into the North-dominated capitalist
world markets.
B. BRINGING THE NlCs to HEEL
There was one area of the South that was relatively untouched
by the first phase of the northern economic counterrevolution.
That was East and Southeast Asia. Here, practically all the
economic systems displayed the same features of state-assisted
capitalism found elsewhere in the South an activist government
intervening in key areas of the economy, a focus on industrialization
in order to escape the fate of being simply agricultural or raw
material producers, protection of the domestic market from foreign
competition, and tight controls on foreign investment. Where the
key East and Southeast Asian economies appeared to differ from
other economies in the South was mainly in the presence of a fairly
strong state that was able to discipline local elites, the greater
internalization of a developmentalist direction by the state elite,
and the pursuit of aggressive mercantilist policies aimed at gaining
markets in First World countries, particularly the United States.
The frontline status in Asia of many of these so-called "Newly
Industrializing Countries" (NlCs) during the Cold War ensured
that Washington would turn a blind eye to many of their deviations
from the free-market ideal. But as the Cold War wound down, the
United States began to redefine its economic policy toward East
Asia as the creation of a "level playing field" for
its corporations via liberalization, deregulation, and more extensive
privatization of Asian economies.
It was a goal that Washington pursued by various means in
the late 1980s and early l990s. However, countries like South
Korea, Thailand, and Indonesia were able to avoid accepting formal
SAPs during the debt crisis because of increased access to Japanese
capital. At that time, Japan was relocating many of its industrial
operations to East and Southeast Asia to offset the loss of competitiveness
in Japan after the 1985 Plaza Accord triggered a rapid appreciation
of the yen. This left unilateralism in trade and financial diplomacy
as the principal U.S. mechanisms for dealing with the increasingly
successful Asian "tigers." Washington's aggressive mood
was aptly captured by a senior U.S. official who told a capital
markets conference in San Francisco, "Although the NlCs may
be regarded as tigers because they are strong, ferocious traders,
the analogy has a darker side. Tigers live in the jungle, and
by the law of the jungle. They are a shrinking population."
Indeed, unilateral pressure, with some assistance from the
IMF and the World Bank, succeeded in getting key Asian countries
to liberalize their capital accounts and to move to greater liberalization
of their financial sectors. But when it came to trade liberalization,
the results were meager, except perhaps in the case of Korea,
whose trade surplus with the United States had been turned into
a trade deficit by the early 1 980s. But even this development
did not change the assessment of Korea by the U.S. Trade Representative
(USTR) as "one of the toughest places in the world to do
business." As for the Southeast Asian countries, Washington's
assessment was that while they might have liberalized their capital
accounts and financial sectors, they remained highly protected
when it came to trade. Some were dangerously flirting with "trade-distorting"
exercises in industrial policy, among which were Malaysia's national
car project, the Proton Saga, and Indonesia's drive to set up
a passenger aircraft industry.
The indiscriminate financial liberalization demanded by Washington
and the Bretton Woods institutions, coupled with the high interest
rate and fixed currency regime favored by local financial authorities,
brought massive amounts of foreign capital into the region. But
it also served as the wide highway through which $100 billion
exited in 1997 in a massive stampede in response to dislocations
caused by overinvestment and unrestricted capital inflows like
the collapse of the real estate market and widening current account
deficits. A golden opportunity to push the U.S. agenda opened
up with the financial crisis, and Washington did not hesitate
to exploit it to the hilt, advancing its interests behind the
banner of free-market reform. The rollback of protectionism and
activist state intervention was incorporated into stabilization
programs imposed by the IMF on the key crisis countries of Indonesia,
Thailand, and South Korea.
In Thailand, local authorities agreed to remove all limitations
on foreign ownership of Thai financial firms, accelerate the privatization
of state enterprises, and revise bankruptcy laws along lines demanded
by the country's foreign creditors. As the USTR proudly told Congress,
the Thai government's "commitments to restructure public
enterprises and accelerate privatization of certain key sectors,
including energy, transportation, utilities, and communications-which
will enhance market-driven competition and deregulation-[are expected]
to create new business opportunities for U.S. firms."
In Indonesia, the USTR emphasized that the IMF's conditions
for granting a massive stabilization package addressed "practices
that have long been the subject of this [Clinton] Administration's
bilateral trade policy...Most notable in this respect is the commitment
by Indonesia to eliminate the tax, tariff, and credit privileges
provided to the national car project. Additionally, the IMF program
seeks broad reform of Indonesian trade and investment policy,
like the aircraft project, monopolies and domestic trade restrictive
practices that stifle competition by limiting access for foreign
goods and services."
The national car project and the plan to set up a passenger
jet aircraft industry were efforts at industrial policy that had
elicited the strong disapproval of Detroit and Boeing, respectively.
In the case of Korea, the U.S. Treasury and the IMF did not
conceal their close working relationship, with the Fund clearly
in a subordinate position. Not surprisingly, the concessions made
by the Koreans were identical to the goals of U.S. bilateral policy
toward the country before the crisis. These included raising the
limit on foreign ownership of corporate stocks to 55 percent,
permitting the establishment of foreign financial institutions,
full liberalization of the financial and capital market, abolition
of the car classification system, and an end to government-directed
lending for industrial policy goals.
As the USTR candidly told members of the U.S. Congress
"Policy-driven rather than market-driven economic activity
meant that U.S. industry encountered many specific structural
barriers to trade, investment, and competition in Korea. For example,
Korea maintained restrictions on foreign ownership and operations,
and had a list of market access impediments...The Korea stabilization
package, negotiated with the IMF in December 1997, should help
open and expand competition in Korea by creating a more market-driven
economy. . .[I]f it continues on the path to reform there will
be important benefits not only for Korea but also the United States."
Summing up Washington's strategic goal, Jeff Garten, under
secretary of Commerce during President Clinton's first term, said,
"Most of these countries are going through a dark and deep
tunnel...But on the other end there is going to be a significantly
different Asia in which American firms have achieved a much deeper
market penetration, much greater access." By 1998, U.S. financial
firms and corporations were buying up Asian assets from Seoul
to Bangkok at fire-sale prices.
C. DISMANTLING THE UN DEVELOPMENT SYSTEM
The assault on the NICs via the IMF stabilization programs
and on the broader South via Bretton Woods-imposed structural
adjustment was accompanied by a major effort to emasculate the
UN as a vehicle for the southern agenda. Wielding the power of
the purse, the United States, which funds some 20 to 25 percent
of the UN budget, moved to silence NIEO rhetoric in all the key
UN institutions dealing with the North-South divide the Economic
and Social Council (ECOSOC), the UNDP, and the General Assembly.
U.S. pressure resulted as well in the effective dismantling of
the UN Center on Transnational Corporations, whose high-quality
work in tracking the activities of global firms in the South had
earned the ire of the corporate community. Also abolished was
the post of director general for International Economic Cooperation
and Development, which had been among the few concrete outcomes,
and certainly the most noteworthy, of the efforts of the developing
countries to secure a stronger UN presence in support of international
economic cooperation and development.
But the focus of the northern counteroffensive was the defanging,
if not dismantling, of UNCTAD. After giving in to the South during
the UNCTAD IV negotiations in Nairobi in 1976 by agreeing to the
creation of the commodity stabilization scheme known as the Integrated
Program for Commodities, the North, during UNCTAD V in Belgrade,
refused the South's program of debt forgiveness and other measures
intended to revive Third World economies and thus contribute to
global recovery at a time of worldwide recession. The northern
offensive escalated during UNCTAD VIII, held in Cartagena in 1992.
At this watershed meeting, the North successfully opposed all
linkages of UNCTAD discussions with the Uruguay Round negotiations
of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and managed
to erode UNCTAD's negotiation functions, thus calling its existence
into question. UNCTAD's main function would henceforth be limited
to "analysis, consensus building on some trade-related issues,
and technical assistance."
This drastic curtailing of UNCTAD's scope was apparently not
enough for certain northern interests. For instance, the Geneva-based
Independent Commission on Global Governance identified UNCTAD
as one of the agencies that could be abolished in order to streamline
the UN system. The commission's views apparently coincided with
that of Karl Theodor Paschke, head of the newly created UN Office
of Internal Oversight Services, who was quoted by Stern magazine
as saying that UNCTAD had been made obsolete by the creation of
the World Trade Organization (WTO). The truth of the matter is
that although UNCTAD continues to survive, it has indeed been
rendered impotent by the WTO, which replaced the less-powerful
GATT following the conclusion of the eight-year Uruguay Round
in 1994.
***
p73
THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION: SEALING THE DEFEAT OF THE SOUTH
The WTO was not the first attempt at a global trading organization.
Forty-six years previous, liberal internationalists had worked
to create such an institution as a third pillar of the Bretton
Woods system, but the threat of nonratification by unilateralist
forces in the U.S. Senate led to its being shelved in favor of
the much weaker GATT by the defensive Truman Administration.
By the mid- I 980s, the United States became the lead advocate
of a much-expanded GATT with real coercive teeth. U.S. officials
were motivated by trade rivalries with Europe and Japan, the rising
import penetration of the U.S. market by Third World countries,
frustration at the inability of U.S. goods to enter southern markets,
and the rise of new competitors in East Asia. Central to the founding
of the WTO were the twin drives of managing the trade rivalry
among the leading industrial countries and containing the threat
posed by the South to the prevailing global economic structure.
In this sense, the WTO must be seen as a continuation or extension
of the same northern reaction that drove structural adjustment.
Indeed, the WTO, by enshrining the principle of free trade
as the organizing principle of the global trading system, represents
the defeat of everything that the South fought for in UNCTAD fair
prices via commodity price agreements; trade preferences to facilitate
economic development in the South preferential treatment for local
investors; the use of trade policy as a legitimate instrument
for industrialization; and a more concerted technology transfer
to the South.
Instead, the WTO institutionalizes free trade, the most-favored
nation principle, and national treatment as the pillars of the
new world trading order. National treatment, established through
the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) of the Uruguay
Round, is perhaps the most revolutionary and the most threatening
to the South. This principle gives foreign service providers,
from telecommunications companies to lawyers to educational agencies,
the same rights and privileges as their domestic counterparts.
Although the GATT-WTO Accord does recognize the "special
and differential status" of the developing countries, it
does not see this as a case of structurally determined differences
but as one of gaps that can be surmounted by giving developing
countries a longer adjustment period than the developed countries.
While northern environmental organizations are critical of the
WTO for subordinating northern environmental standards to the
principle that Lori Wallach of Public Citizen describes as "free
trade, uber alles," the southern countries have articulated
their concerns about the GATT-WTO's antidevelopmental thrust.
In their view, GATT-WTO is inherently unsympathetic to industrialization
at the same time that it erodes the agricultural base of the developing
societies.
A. THE WTO AND INDUSTRIALIZATION IN THE SOUTH
In signing on to GATT, Third World countries have agreed to
ban all quantitative restrictions on imports, to reduce tariffs
on many industrial imports, and not to raise tariffs on all other
imports. In so doing, they have effectively given up the use of
trade policy to pursue industrialization objectives. The way that
the NICC made it to industrial status, via the policy of import
substitution, is now effectively removed as a route to industrialization.
The anti-industrialization thrust of the GATT-WTO Accord is
made even more manifest in the Agreement on Trade-Related Investment
Measures (TRIMs) and the Agreement on Trade Related Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPs). These agreements deny countries the right
to pursue some of the policies that the NlCs used successfully
in their drive to industrialize. For example, countries like South
Korea and Malaysia used trade-balancing requirements, which tied
the value of a foreign investor's imports of raw materials and
components to the value of his or her exports of the finished
commodity, and "local content" regulations, which mandated
that a certain percentage of the components that went into the
making of a product be sourced locally.
These rules enabled the NlCs to raise income from capital
intensive exports, develop support industries, and bring in technology,
while still protecting local entrepreneurs' preferential access
to the domestic market. In Malaysia, for instance, the strategic
use of local content policy enabled them to build a "national
car," in cooperation with Mitsubishi, that has now achieved
about 80 percent local content and controls 70 percent of the
Malaysian market. Thanks to the TRIMs accord, these mechanisms
are now illegal.
Like TRIMs, the TRIPs regime is seen as an obstacle to the
industrialization efforts of Third World countries. TRIPs provides
a generalized minimum patent protection of 20 years; increases
the duration of the protection for semiconductors or computer
chips; institutes draconian border regulations against products
judged to be violating intellectual property rights; and places
the burden of proof on the presumed violator of process patents.
These requirements make it more difficult for developing countries
to have the level of access to cutting-edge technologies that
was enjoyed by the NlCs and almost all late-industrializing countries.
The United States industrialized, to a great extent, by using
but paying very little for British manufacturing innovations,
as did the Germans. Japan industrialized by liberally borrowing
U.S. technological innovations, but barely compensating the Americans
for this. And the Koreans industrialized by quite liberally copying
U.S. and Japanese product and process technologies.
But what is "technological diffusion" from the perspective
of the late industrializer is "piracy" from that of
the industrial leader. The TRIPs regime takes the side of the
latter and will make the process of industrialization by imitation
much more difficult from now on. It represents what UNCTAD describes
as "a premature strengthening of the intellectual property
system...that favors monopolistically controlled innovation over
broad-based diffusion."
Southern countries perceive TRIPs as a victory for the U.S.
high-tech industry, which has long been lobbying for stronger
controls over the diffusion of innovations. Innovation in the
knowledge-intensive high-tech sector-in electronic software and
hardware, biotechnology, lasers, optoelectronics, and liquid crystal
technology, to name a few-has become the central determinant of
economic power in our time. And when any company in the NlCs and
Third World wishes to innovate, say in chip design, software programming,
or computer assembly, it necessarily has to integrate several
patented designs and processes, most of them from U.S. electronic
hardware and software giants like Microsoft, Intel, and Texas
Instruments. As the Koreans have bitterly learned, exorbitant
multiple royalty payments to what has been called the American
"high-tech mafia" keeps one's profit margins very low
while reducing incentives for local innovation. The likely outcome
is for a southern manufacturer simply to pay royalties for a technology
rather than to innovate, thus perpetuating the technological dependence
on northern firms.
Thus, TRIPs enables the technological leader, in this case
the United States, to greatly influence the pace of technological
and industrial development in rival industrialized countries,
the NlCs, and the Third World.
***
p83
D. OLIGARCHIC DECISION MAKING
There are other inequalities structured into the WTO system.
The system of decision making is perhaps among the most blatant
of these. Pro-WTO propaganda has projected the agency as a "one
nation/one vote" organization, where the United States has
no more votes than Rwanda or the Dominican Republic. In fact,
it is quite undemocratic and is actually run by an oligarchy of
countries, much like the World Bank and the IMF. Were majority
rule to prevail, then the WTO would, like the UN General Assembly,
be structurally more responsive to the needs of the South. But,
as it did at the World Bank and the IMF, the North evolved other
mechanisms of control. While at the Bank and the Fund the prime
mechanism of control is the size of rich countries' financial
contributions, which gives them enormous voting power vis-a-vis
the mass of developing countries, at the WTO, northern domination
is achieved via what is euphemistically referred to as "consensus."
This process was described in the following manner before
the U.S. Congress by an influential WTO advocate after noting
that there had not been a vote taken in GATT, the WTO's predecessor,
since 1959, economist C. Fred Bergsten underlined that the WTO
"does not work by voting. It works by a consensus arrangement
which, to tell the truth, is managed by four-the Quads the United
States, Japan, European Union, and Canada." He continued
"Those countries have to agree if any major steps are going
to be made, that is true. But no votes. I do not anticipate votes
in the new institution."
The way that the consensus rule assures the hegemony of the
North was recently on display in the selection of the successor
to Renato Ruggiero as director general. The U.S.-led bloc that
successfully supported New Zealander Mike Moore refused a head
count, as proposed by backers of Thailand's Supachai, on grounds
that this would violate the WTO's consensus tradition.
Indeed, so undemocratic is the WTO that decisions are arrived
at informally, via caucuses convoked in the corridors of the ministerials
by the big trading powers. The formal sessions are reserved for
speeches. The key agreements to come out of the first and second
ministerials of the WTO-the decision to liberalize information
technology trade taken in Singapore in 1996 and the agreement
to liberalize trade in electronic commerce arrived at in Geneva
in 1998-were decided on in informal backroom sessions and simply
presented to the full assembly as faits accomplis. It is against
this dismal background that we now move to the question of reform.
Views
from the South
Index
of Website
Home
Page