Sustainable Development
Conventional versus Emergent Alternative Wisdom
by David Korten
EDucate magazine, January-March, 2002
An important starting point in any discussion of sustainable
development is to clarify the basic assumptions we each bring
to the table. While the views of sustainable development cover
a broad spectrum, the following contrast of the conventional wisdom
and the emergent alternative wisdom on this subject helps to define
the range. Most of the economists, governments and official agencies
(including the World Bank, IMF, and the GATT) that define national
and global policies profess the conventional wisdom. A growing
number of alternative economists, independent thinkers, and citizen
organizations concerned with economic justice and environmental
issues are engaged in articulating and elaborating the alternative
wisdom as the foundation for policies they hope will prove to
he more people and environment friendly. Which best captures your
view of sustainable development?
Sustainable Development
Conventional:
Sustainable development is about achieving the sustained economic
growth needed to meet human needs, improve living standards, and
provide the financial resources that make environmental protection
possible.
Alternative:
Little of the growth of the past twenty years has improved the
quality of human life. Most of the benefit has gone to the very
wealthy and the remainder has been offset by the costs of resource
depletion, social stress, and environmental health and other problems
caused by growth. Sustainable development is about creating:
I) sustainable economies that equitably meet human needs without
extracting resource inputs or expelling wastes in excess of the
environment's regenerative capacity, and
II) sustainable human institutions that assure both security
and opportunity for social, intellectual, and spiritual growth.
Sustainable Lifestyle
Conventional:
Adopting less resource intensive lifestyles means going backwards,
accepting a lowered standard of living. Given the current trend
towards declining rates of population growth, any apparent limits
to growth will be eliminated by continuing technological advance
and the operation of market mechanisms. Responding to ill-advised
calls to end growth is not necessary and would he a tragic error
condemning billions of people to perpetual poverty.
Alternative:
Consumption of environmental resources already exceeds sustainable
limits. The central task of development must be to reallocate
the use of sustainable resource flows. This will require that
current high consumers significantly reduce their per capita resource
consumption. This may reduce their standard of living as defined
purely by physical consumption, but it also offers opportunities
for an improved quality of personal family and community life.
Necessary reductions can be accomplished in part by reforming
production systems to maximize recycling and minimize dependence
on inputs from and waste disposal to the environment. Some nonessential
forms of consumption may need to he eliminated.
Helping Poor Countries Become Sustainable
Conventional:
Once poor countries are on the path to sustainable growth, an
expanding economic pie will allow them to address a wide range
of needs, including environmental protection and the elimination
of poverty. Achieving sustainable growth in the South depends
on accelerating economic growth in the North to spur demand for
Southern exports and thus stimulate Southern economies. Of course,
if it is to fully benefit the South, accelerated growth in the
North must be combined with the removal of trade barriers and
increases in foreign investment and foreign aid including environmental
lending.
Alternative:
Environmental problems are in large part a consequence of Northern
countries exporting their ecological deficits to the South through
trade and investment. The appropriation of environmental resources
and sinks to service Northern over consumption, limits the per
capita shares of these resources available in Southern countries
to meet domestic needs and pushes the economically weak to marginal
ecological areas. Much of existing foreign aid, loans and investment,
create Southern economies that are deeply in debt to the North
and dependent on the continuing import of Northern technology
and products. This creates demands for ever greater foreign exchange
earnings for imports, debt service and repatriation of profits
by foreign investors that can be obtained only through further
depletion and export of environmental resources. Sustainable development
in poor countries depends on:
1) increasing the availability, accessibility, and quality
of sustainable natural resource flows to meet the basic human
needs of their own people, 2) and the political, institutional,
and technical capacity to use their resources efficiently and
to distribute the benefits equitably among all members of current
and future generations.
Northern countries best contribute to achieving this outcome
in Southern countries by:
1 ) limiting their own consumption to reduce Northern dependence
on environmental subsidies extracted from the South and release
resources for use by the poor to meet their basic needs, 2) and
facilitating unrestricted Southern access to socially and environmentally
beneficial technologies.
Responsibility for Environmental Problems
Conventional:
Poverty is the primary cause of environmental problems. Because
of lack of education and economic opportunities the poor have
too many children and lack the sensitivity and resources to provide
the care for their environment that wealthier people and countries
do. Environmental quality is a low priority for people whose survival
is in question. They will become concerned about and invest in
environmental conservation only once a certain level of income
is attained. Stimulating economic growth to increase employment
opportunities and incomes must be the foundation of environmental
protection.
[There is not a clear alternative consensus. Alternative I
is the more prevalent among alternative thinkers, particularly
in the South.]
Alternative I:
The over consumption of Northern countries is the problem. Therefore
Northern population growth is an issue because of the substantial
consumption each additional Northerner adds. The poor consume
very little so their numbers are not environmentally important
and Southern population growth is not issue.
Alternative II:
Inequality is the fundamental cause of environmental problems.
Because of their much greater relative power in a market economy,
the wealthy are able to pass on the social and ecological costs
of their over consumption to the poor. Since the poor are the
first to suffer from environmental degradation, they are in many
localities becoming leading advocates of more environmentally
responsible resource management practices. Where poverty appears
to be the cause of environmental destruction it is usually because
the poor have been deprived of other means of livelihood and thus
have been pushed in desperation to over exploit environmentally
fragile lands. Often their lack of any other source of security
creates an incentive to have many children. Eliminating inequality
by distributing resource control more equitably is a fundamental
condition for sustainability.
Population
Conventional:
Population will stabilize naturally at somewhere between 12 and
15 billion people. While this will create some strains, with adequate
economic growth it should not be a consequential problem.
Alternative:
In the absence of radical economic reforms intended to rapidly
accelerate reductions in fertility by increasing equity, social
security, and investment in female education, female livelihood
opportunities, health, and family planning services, the global
population will be naturally stabilized well below 12 billion
by catastrophic events as social and ecological stress result
in mass starvation and violence. Given current dependence on the
depletion of nonrenewable ecological reserves, it is doubtful
that even the world's current population is truly sustainable
if minimum acceptable levels of consumption are to be maintained.
Economic Management Goals
Conventional:
The primary goal of economic policy is the efficient allocation
of resources. The internalization of production costs is a precondition
to efficient allocation by markets and therefore must also be
a goal of policy. Equity is a secondary by-product of economically
efficient markets.
Alternative:
There are three basic goals that economic policy must seek to
optimize. In order of relative importance these are: a scale of
resource use, consistent with ecological regenerative capacities,
a fair distribution of resources, and the economically efficient
allocation of resources. Efficient market allocation requires
the internalization of all costs of production, including the
social and environmental costs.
Jobs
Conventional:
Jobs are created through economic growth
Alternative:
We have entered an era of jobless growth in which technology and
reorganizations are eliminating good jobs faster than growth is
creating them. The new jobs being created are often low paying,
temporary, and without benefits, creating an underlying sense
of insecurity throughout society that deeply stresses the social
fabric. Furthermore, many of the jobs provided by the conventional
economy are based on unsustainable rates of resource extraction
and are therefore temporary in nature. We must begin to think
in terms of providing people with sustainable livelihoods based
on sustainable production for sustainable markets to support sustainable
lifestyles. There is a great deal of useful, environmentally dirty
work that needs to be done that could readily eliminate involuntary
unemployment if we chose to do so. Furthermore, in most instances
sustainable production methods and technologies provide more livelihood
opportunities than do their alternatives.
Trade and the Environment
Conventional:
Free (unregulated) trade increases economic efficiency through
comparative advantage. Economic efficiency means better use of
resources, which is environmentally advantageous. Increased trade
also increases overall economic growth, thereby producing the
resources needed for environmental protection. The greater the
volume of trade the greater the benefit to the environment.
Alternative:
Trade is useful where gains from comparative advantage are real.
More than half of all international trade involves exchanges of
the same goods, which suggests there is little or no comparative
advantage involved. To be fair and economically efficient, trade
must be carried out within a clear framework of rules: 1) internalize
total costs (production, social and environmental costs, including
the full costs of transport); and 2) maintain balanced trade relations.
Free (unregulated) trade leads to competition between localities
in need of jobs to reduce costs of local production by suppressing
wages and allowing maximum externalization of environmental, social,
and even production costs which is both inefficient and highly
damaging to the environment and to social standards.
Markets and Governments
Conventional:
Markets allocate resources most efficiently when there is the
least government interference. Consumers express their preferences
through their purchasing decisions, with the consequence that
in the aggregate the market reflects the value preferences of
the society as to how scarce resources are best allocated. When
governments intervene they distort the price signals and efficiency
is reduced. In performing any given function markets tend to be
more efficient than governments. Therefore it is desirable to
privatize functions wherever possible, while providing incentives
to private investors to create jobs and increase foreign exchange
earnings.
Alternative:
The market is an essential institution in any workable economic
allocation system. However, by its nature, the market reflects
only the preferences for private goods of those who have money.
Without the intervention of government and a vigilant civil society,
a free (unregulated) market takes no account of optimal scale
or of the needs of those without money, neglects essential needs
for public goods, externalizes a significant portion of real production
costs, and tends toward monopoly control of allocation decisions
by the market's winners. When conventional wisdom calls for incentives
for private investors, it is in fact calling for subsidies that
commonly take the form of agreeing to let firms increase their
private gain by transferring a larger portion of their production
costs to the public. To achieve social justice and environmental
sustainability, government must intervene to setup a framework
that assures full costs are internalized, competition is maintained,
benefits are justly distributed, and necessary public goods are
provided. A vigilant and vigorous civil society is required to
assure the accountability of both government and market to the
public interest and to provide leadership in advancing social
innovation processes.
Scientific Foundation
Conventional:
The conventional wisdom is grounded in accepted theory that has
stood the test of time and been validated by extensive historical
observation and measurement.
Alternative:
The conventional wisdom represents an ideology, not a science,
and largely contradicts both the theoretical foundations of market
economics and empirical experience which contrary to the claims
of the conventional wisdom strongly favor the alternative wisdom.
Indeed, the conventional wisdom may itself be the single greatest
barrier we face to progress toward sustainability.
Revised September 11, 1996. Originally prepared for the Office
of Technology Assessment, United States Congress, Washington,
DC
About David C. Korten
David C. Korten is Co-founder and Board Chair, Positive Futures
Network, publishers of YES! A Journal of Positive Futures and
Founder and President of The People-Centered Development Forum.
He has over thirty-five years of experience in preeminent business,
academic, and international development institutions as well as
in contemporary citizen action organizations. His work in South
East Asia won him international recognition for his contributions
to pioneering the development of powerful strategies for transforming
public bureaucracies into responsive support systems dedicated
to strengthening community control and management of land, water,
and forestry resources. Korten came to realize that the crisis
of deepening poverty, growing inequality, environmental devastation,
and social disintegration he was observing in Asia was also being
experienced in nearly every country in the world-including the
United States and other "developed" countries. Furthermore
he came to the conclusion that the United States was actively
promoting-both at home and abroad-the very policies that were
deepening the resulting global crisis. He is the author of "When
Corporations Rule the World" and "The Post-Corporate
World: Life After Capitalism". His publications are required
reading in university courses around the world.
David
Korten page
Corporate
watch
Index
of Website
Home
Page