Lost in Transition
excerpted from the book
The Shock Doctrine
The Rise of Disaster Capitalism
by Naomi Klein
Picador, 2007, paperback
p213
Stephan Haggard and John Williamson, The Political Economy of
Policy Reform, 1994
These worst of times give rise to the
best of opportunities for those who understand the need for fundamental
economic reform.
p215
William Browder, a U.S. money manager, on investing in Poland
in the early days of capitalism
There's a certain chemical that gets released
in your stomach when you make ten times your money. And it's addictive.
p232
Deng Xiaoping was enthusiastically committed to converting to
a corporate-based economy-so committed that, in 1980, his government
invited Milton Friedman to come to China and tutor hundreds of
top-level civil servants, professors and party economists in the
fundamentals of free-market theory. "All were invited guests,
who had to show a ticket of invitation to attend," Friedman
recalled of his audiences in Beijing and Shanghai. His central
message was "how much better ordinary people lived in capitalist
than in communist countries." The example he held up was
Hong .Kong, a zone of pure capitalism that Friedman had long admired
for its "dynamic, innovative character that has been produced
by personal liberty, free trade, low taxes, and minimal government
intervention." He claimed that Hong Kong, despite having
no democracy, was freer than the United States, since its government
participated less in the economy.
Friedman's definition of freedom, in which
political freedoms were incidental, even unnecessary, compared
with the freedom of unrestricted commerce, conformed nicely with
the vision taking shape in the Chinese Politburo. The party wanted
to open the economy to private ownership and consumerism while
maintaining its own grip on power-a plan that ensured that once
the assets of the state were auctioned off, party officials and
their relatives would snap up the best deals and be first in line
for the biggest profits. According to this version of "transition,"
the same people who controlled the state under Communism would
control it under capitalism, while enjoying a substantial upgrade
in lifestyle. The model the Chinese government intended to emulate
was not the United States but something much closer to Chile under
Pinochet: free markets combined with authoritarian political control,
enforced by iron-fisted repression.
... in 1983, as Deng opened up the country
to foreign investment and reduced protections for workers, he
also ordered the creation of the 400,000-strong People's Armed
Police, a new, roving riot squad charged with quashing all signs
of 'economic crimes" (i.e., strikes and protests).
... Many of Deng's reforms were successful
and popular-farmers had more control over their lives, and commerce
returned to the cities. But in the late eighties, Deng began introducing
measures that were distinctly unpopular, particularly among workers
in the cities - price controls were lifted, sending prices soaring;
job security was eliminated, creating waves of unemployment; and
deep inequalities were opening up between the winners and losers
in the new China. By 1988, the party was confronting a powerful
backlash and was forced to reverse some of its price deregulation.
Outrage was also mounting in the face of the party's defiant corruption
and nepotism. Many Chinese citizens wanted more freedom in the
market, but "reform" increasingly looked like code for
party officials turning into business tycoons, as many illegally
took possession of the assets they had previously managed as bureaucrats.
p235
The most visible symbols of the opposition were the demonstrations
by student strikers in Tiananmen Square. These historic protests
were almost universally portrayed in the international media as
a clash between modern, idealistic students who wanted Western-style
democratic freedoms and old-guard authoritarians who wanted to
protect the Communist state. Recently, another analysis of the
meaning of Tiananmen has emerged, one that challenges the mainstream
version while pulling Friedmanism at the heart of the story. This
alternative narrative is being advanced by, among others, Wang
Hui, one of the organizers of the 1989 protests, and now a leading
Chinese intellectual of what is known as China's "New Left."
In his 2003 book, China's New Order, Wang explains that the protesters
spanned a huge range of Chinese society-not just elite university
students but also factory workers, small entrepreneurs and teachers.
What ignited the protests, he recalls, was popular discontent
in the face of Deng's "revolutionary" economic changes,
which were lowering wages, raising prices and causing "a
crisis of layoffs and unemployment. According to Wang, "These
changes were the catalyst for the 1989 social mobilization."
The demonstrations were not against economic
reform per se; they were against the specific Friedmanite nature
of the reforms - their speed, ruthlessness and the fact that the
process was highly antidemocratic. Wang says that the protesters'
call for elections and free speech were intimately connected to
this economic dissent. What drove the demand for democracy was
the fact that the party was pushing through changes that were
revolutionary in scope, entirely without popular consent. There
was, he writes, "a general request for democratic means to
supervise the fairness of the reform process and the reorganization
of social benefits."
These demands forced the Politburo to
make a definite choice. The choice was not, as was so often claimed,
between democracy and Communism, or "reform" versus
the "old guard." It was a more complex calculation:
Should the party bulldoze ahead with its free-market agenda, which
it could do only by rolling over the bodies of the protesters?
Or should it bow to the protesters' demands for democracy, cede
its monopoly on power and risk a major setback to the economic
project?
Some of the free-market reformers within
the party, most notably General Secretary Zhao Ziyang, appeared
willing to gamble on democracy, convinced that economic and political
reform could still be compatible. More powerful elements in the
party were not willing to take the risk. The verdict came down:
the state would protect its economic "reform" program
by crushing the demonstrators.
That was the clear message when, on May
20, 1989, the government of the People's Republic of China declared
martial law. On June 3, the tanks of the People's Liberation Army
rolled into the protests, shooting indiscriminately into the crowds.
Soldiers stormed onto buses where student demonstrators were taking
cover and beat them with sticks; more troops broke through the
barricades protecting Tiananmen Square, where students had erected
a Goddess of Democracy statue, and rounded up the organizers.
Similar crackdowns took place simultaneously across the country.
There will never be reliable estimates
for how many people were killed and injured in those days. The
party admits to hundreds, and eyewitness reports at the time put
the number of dead at between two thousand and seven thousand
and the number of injured as high as thirty thousand. The protests
were followed by a national witch hunt against all regime critics
and opponents. Some forty thousand were arrested, thousands were
jailed and many-possibly hundreds-were executed. As in Latin America,
the government reserved its harshest repression for the factory
workers, who represented the most direct threat to deregulated
capitalism. "Most of those arrested, and virtually all who
were executed, were workers. With the obvious aim of terrorizing
the population, it became a well-publicized policy to systematically
subject arrested individuals to beatings and torture," writes
Maurice Meisner.
p238
/Five days after the bloody crackdown, Deng addressed the nation
and made it perfectly clear that it wasn't Communism he was protecting
with his crackdown, but capitalism. After dismissing the protesters
as "a large quantity of the dregs o society," China's
president reaffirmed the party's commitment to economic shock
therapy. "In a word, this was a test, and we passed,"
Deng said, adding, "Perhaps this bad thing will enable us
to go ahead with reform and the open-door policy at a more steady,
better, even a faster pace .... We haven't been wrong. There's
nothing wrong with the four cardinal principles [of economic reform].
If there is anything amiss, it's that these principles haven't
been thoroughly implemented "
Orville Schell, a China scholar and journalist,
summarized Deng Xiaoping's choice: "After the massacre of
1989, he in effect said we will not stop economic reform; we will
in effect halt political reform."
For Deng and the rest of the Politburo,
the free-market possibilities were now limitless. Just as Pinochet's
terror had cleared the streets for revolutionary change, so Tiananmen
paved the way for a radical transformation free from fear of rebellion.
If life grew harder for peasants and workers, they would either
have to accept it quietly or face the wrath of the army and the
secret police. And so, with the public in a state of raw terror,
Deng rammed through his most sweeping reforms yet.
... It was this wave of reforms that turned
China into the sweatshop the world, the preferred location for
contract factories for virtually every multinational on the planet.
No country offered more lucrative conditions than China: low taxes
and tariffs, corruptible officials and, most of all, a plentiful
low-wage workforce that, for many years, would be unwilling to
risk demanding decent salaries or the most basic workplace protections
for fear of the most violent reprisals.
For foreign investors and the party, it
has been a win-win arrangement. According to a 2006 study, 90
percent of China's billionaires (calculated in Chinese yuan) are
the children of Communist Party officials. Roughly twenty-nine
hundred of these party scions - known as "the princelings"
- control $260 billion, It is a mirror of the corporatist state
first pioneered in Chile under Pinochet: a revolving to between
corporate and political elites who combine their power to eliminate
workers as an organized political force.
... One of the truths revealed by Tiananmen
was the stark similarity between the tactics of authoritarian
Communism and Chicago School capitalism-a shared willingness to
disappear opponents, to blank the slate of all resistance and
begin anew.
Despite the fact that the massacre happened
just months after he had encouraged Chinese officials to push
forward with painful and unpopular free-market policies, Friedman
never did face "an avalanche of protests for having been
willing to give advice to so evil a government." And as usual,
he saw no connection between the advice he had given and the violence
required to enforce it. While condemning China's use of repression,
Friedman continued to hold it up as an example of "the efficacy
of free-market arrangements in promoting both prosperity and freedom.
p246
In January 1990, Nelson Mandela, age seventy-one, sat down in
his prison compound to write a note to his supporters outside.
It was meant to settle a debate over whether twenty-seven years
behind bars, most of it spent on Robben Island off the coast of
Cape Town, had weakened the leader's commitment to the economic
transformation of South Africa's apartheid state. The note was
only two sentences long, and it decisively put the matter to rest.
"The nationalisation of he mines, banks and monopoly industries
is the policy of the ANC, and the change or modification of our
views in this regard is inconceivable. Black economic empowerment
is a goal we fully support and encourage, but in our situation
state control of certain sectors of economy is unavoidable."
... In South Africa, the largest economy
on the African continent, it seemed that some people still believed
that freedom included the right to reclaim and redistribute their
oppressors' ill-gotten gains.
That belief had formed the basis of the
policy of the African National Congress for thirty-five years,
ever since it was spelled out in its statement of core principles,
the Freedom Charter.
... The charter enshrines the right to
work, to decent housing, to freedom of thought, and, most radically,
to a share in the wealth of the richest country in Africa, containing,
among other treasures, the largest goldfield in the world. "The
national wealth of our country, the heritage of South Africans,
shall be restored to the people; the mineral wealth beneath the
soil, the Banks and monopoly industry shall be transferred to
the ownership of the people as a whole; all other industry and
trade shall be controlled to assist the well-being of the people,"
the charter states.
p249
If Mandela led the ANC to power and nationalized the banks and
the mines, the precedent would make it far more difficult for
Chicago School economists to dismiss such proposals in other countries
as relics of the past and insist that only unfettered free markets
and free trade had the ability to redress deep inequalities.
... In the years that passed between Mandela's
writing his note from prison and the ANC's 1994 election sweep
in which he was elected president, something happened to convince
the party hierarchy that it could not use its grassroots prestige
to reclaim and redistribute the country's stolen wealth. So, rather
than meeting in the middle between California and the Congo, the
ANC adopted policies that exploded both inequality and crime to
such a degree that South Africa's divide is now closer to Beverly
Hills and Baghdad. Today, the country stands as a living testament
to what happens when economic reform is severed from political
transformation. Politically, its people have the right to vote,
civil liberties and majority rule. Yet economically, South Africa
has surpassed Brazil as the most unequal society in the world.
p252
Running alongside these often explosive summits were the much
lower profile economic negotiations, primarily managed on the
ANC side by Thabo Mbeki, then a rising star in the party, now
South Africa's president. As the political talks progressed, and
it became clear to the National Party that Parliament would soon
be firmly in the hands of the ANC, the party of South Africa's
elites began pouring its energy and creativity into the economic
negotiations. South Africa's whites had failed to keep blacks
from taking over the government, but when it came to safeguarding
the wealth they had amassed under apartheid, they would not give
up so easily.
In these talks, the de Klerk government
had a twofold strategy. First, drawing on the ascendant Washington
Consensus that there was now only one way to run an economy, it
portrayed key sectors of economic decision making-such as trade
policy and the central bank-as "technical" or "administrative."
Then it used a wide range of new policy tools- international trade
agreements, innovations in constitutional law and structural adjustment
programs-to hand control of those power centers to supposedly
impartial experts, economists and officials from the IMF, the
World Bank, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GAIT)
and the National Party-anyone except the liberation fighters from
the ANC. It was a strategy of balkanization, not of the country's
geography (as de Klerk had originally attempted) but of its economy.
This plan was successfully executed under
the noses of ANC leaders, who were naturally preoccupied with
winning the battle to control Parliament. In the process, the
ANC failed to protect itself against a far more insidious strategy-in
essence, an elaborate insurance plan against the economic clauses
in the Freedom Charter ever becoming law in South Africa. "The
people shall govern!" would soon become a reality, but the
sphere over which they would govern was shrinking fast.
p253
As one of the few classically trained economists active in the
ANC, [Vishnu] Padayachee was enlisted to play a leading role in
Make Democracy Work ("doing the number-crunching," as
he puts it). Most of the people he worked alongside in those long
policy meetings went on to top posts in the ANC government, but
Padayachee did not. He has turned down all the offers of government
jobs, preferring academic life in Durban, where he teaches, writes
and owns the much-loved Ike's Bookshop, named after Ike Mayet,
the first nonwhite South African bookseller. It was there, surrounded
by carefully preserved out-of-print volumes on African history,
that we met to discuss the transition.
... In late 1993, when he and a colleague
from the Make Democracy Work group got a call from the negotiating
team who were in the final stages of haggling with the National
Party. The call was a request for them to write a position paper
on the pros and cons of making South Africa's central bank an
independent entity, run with total autonomy from the elected government
- oh, and the negotiators needed it by morning.
'We were caught completely off guard,
recalled Padayachee, now in his early fifties. He had done his
graduate studies at Johns Hopkins University in Baltimore. He
knew that at the time, even among free-market economists in the
U.S., central bank independence was considered a fringe idea,
a pet policy of a handful of Chicago School ideologues who believed
that central banks should be run as sovereign republics within
states, out of reach of the meddling hands of elected lawmakers.*
For Padayachee and his colleagues, who strongly believed that
monetary policy needed to serve the new government's "big
goals of growth, employment and redistribution," the ANC's
position was a no-brainer: "There was not going to be an
independent central bank in South Africa."
p255
What happened in those negotiations is that the ANC found itself
caught in a new kind of web, one made of arcane rules and regulations,
all designed to confine and constrain the power of elected leaders.
As the web descended on the country, only a few people even noticed
it was there, but when the new government came to power and tried
to move freely, to give its voters the tangible benefits of liberation
they expected and thought they had voted for, the strands of the
web tightened and the administration discovered that its powers
were tightly bound. Patrick Bond, who worked as an economic adviser
in Mandela's office during the first years of ANC rule, recalls
that the in-house quip was "Hey, we've got the state, where's
the power?" As the new government attempted to make tangible
the dreams of the Freedom Charter, it discovered that the power
was elsewhere.
Want to redistribute land? Impossible
-at the last minute, the negotiators agreed to add a clause to
the new constitution that protects all private property, making
land reform virtually impossible. Want to create jobs for millions
of unemployed workers? Can't-hundreds of factories were actually
about to close because the ANC had signed on to the GAIT, the
precursor to the World Trade Organization, which made it illegal
to subsidize the auto plants and textile factories. Want to get
free AIDS drugs to the townships, where the disease is spreading
with terrifying speed? That violates an intellectual property
rights commitment under the WTO, which the ANC joined with no
public debate as a continuation of the GAIT. Need money to build
more and larger houses for the poor and to bring free electricity
to the townships? Sorry-the budget is being eaten up servicing
the massive debt, passed on quietly by the apartheid government.
Print more money? Tell that to the apartheid-era head of the central
bank. Free water for all? Not likely. The World Bank, with its
large in-country contingent of economists, researchers and trainers
(a self-proclaimed "Knowledge Bank"), is making private-sector
partnerships the service norm. Want to impose currency controls
to guard against wild speculation? That would violate the $850
million IMF deal, signed, conveniently enough, right before the
elections. Raise the minimum wage to close the apartheid income
gap? Nope. The IMF deal promises "wage restraint." 12
And don't even think about ignoring these commitments-any change
will be regarded as evidence of dangerous national untrustworthiness,
a lack of commitment to "reform," an absence of a "rules-based
system." All of which will lead to currency crashes, aid
cuts and capital flight. The bottom line was that South Africa
was free but simultaneously captured; each one of these arcane
acronyms represented a different thread in the web that pinned
down the limbs of the new government.
A longtime antiapartheid activist, Rassool
Snyman, described the trap to me in stark terms. "They never
freed us. They only took the chain from around our neck and put
it on our ankles." Yasmin Sooka, a prominent South African
human rights activist, told me that the transition "was business
saying, 'We'll keep everything and you [the ANC] will rule in
name .... You can have political power, you can have the façade
of governing, but the real governance will take place somewhere
" It was a process of infantilization that is common to so-called
transitional countries-new governments are, in effect, given the
keys to the house but not the combination to the safe.
p257
It was the Chicago Boys in Chile, fittingly, who pioneered this
process of democracy-proofing capitalism, or building what they
called "new democracy." In Chile, before handing over
power to an elected government after seventeen years of junta
rule, the Chicago Boys rigged the constitution and the courts
so it was legally next to impossible to reverse their revolutionary
laws. They had many names for this process: building a "technified
democracy," a "protected democracy," or, as Pinochet's
young minister José Piñera put it, ensuring "insulation
from politics."
p259
In the first two years of ANC rule, the party still tried to use
the limited ( resources it had to
make good on the promise of redistribution. There was a flurry
of public investment-more than
a hundred thousand homes were built for the poor, and millions
were hooked up to water,
electricity and phone lines. 14 But, in a familiar story, weighed
down by debt and under international pressure to privatize these
services, the government soon began raising prices. After a decade
of ANC rule, millions of people had been cut off from newly connected
water and electricity because they couldn't pay the bills.* At
least 40 percent of the new phones lines were no longer in service
by 2003. As for the "banks, mines and monopoly industry"
that Mandela had pledged to nationalize, they remained firmly
in the hands of the same four white-owned megaconglomerates that
also control 80 percent of the Johannesburg Stock Exchange. 16
In 2005, only 4 percent of the companies listed on the exchange
were owned or controlled by blacks." Seventy percent of South
Africa's land, in 2006, was still monopolized by whites, who are
just 10 percent of the population. Most distressingly, the ANC
government has spent far more time denying the severity of the
AIDS crisis than getting lifesaving drugs to the approximately
5 million people infected with HIV, though there were, by early
2007, some positive signs of progress. Perhaps the most striking
statistic is this one: since 1990, the year Mandela left prison,
the average life expectancy for South Africans has dropped by
thirteen years.
... the party could have attempted to
launch a second liberation movement and break free of the asphyxiating
web that had been spun during the transition. Or it could simply
accept its restricted power and embrace the new economic order.
The ANC's leadership chose the second option. Rather than making
the centerpiece of its policy the redistribution of wealth that
was already in the country-the core of the Freedom Charter on
which it had been elected-the ANC, once it became the government,
accepted the dominant logic that its only hope was to pursue new
foreign investors who would create new wealth, the benefits of
which would trickle down to the poor for the trickle-down model
to have a hope of working, the ANC government had to radically
alter its behavior to make itself appealing to investors.
This was not an easy task, as Mandela
had learned when he walked out of prison. As soon as he was released,
the South African stock market collapsed in panic; South Africa's
currency, the rand, dropped by 10 percent.' A few weeks later,
De Beers, the diamond corporation, moved its headquarters from
South Africa to Switzerland. This kind of instant punishment from
the markets would have been unimaginable three decades earlier,
when Mandela was first imprisoned. In the sixties, it was unheard
of for multinationals to switch nationalities on a whim and, back
then, the world money system was still firmly linked to the gold
standard. Now South Africa's currency had been stripped of controls,
trade barriers were down and most trading was short-term speculation.
Not only did the volatile market not like
the idea of a liberated Mandela, but just a few misplaced words
from him or his fellow ANC leaders could lead to an earth-shaking
stampede by what the New York Times columnist Thomas Friedman
has aptly termed "the electronic herd... he stampede that
greeted Mandela's release was just the start of what became a
call-and-response between the leadership and the financial markets-a
shock dialogue that trained the party in the new rules of the
game. Every time a top party official said something that hinted
that the ominous Freedom Charter might still become policy, the
market responded with a shock, sending the rand into free fall.
The rules were simple and crude, the electronic equivalent of
monosyllabic grunts: justice-expensive sell status quo - good,
buy.
p262
Of all the constraints on the new government, it was the market
that proved most confining - and this, in a way, is the genius
of unfettered capitalism: it's self-enforcing. Once countries
have opened themselves up to the global market's temperamental
moods, any departure from Chicago School orthodoxy is instantly
punished by traders in New York and London who bet against the
offending country's currency, causing a deeper crisis and the
need for more loans, with more conditions attached. Mandela acknowledged
the trap in 1997, telling the ANC's national conference, "The
very mobility of capital and the globalisation of the capital
and other markets, make it impossible for countries, for instance,
to decide national economic policy without regard to the likely
response of these markets."
The person inside the ANC who seemed to
understand how to make the shocks stop was Thabo Mbeki, Mandela's
right hand during his presidency and soon to be his successor.
... The beast of the market had been unleashed,
Mbeki would explain; there was no taming it, just feeding it what
it craved: growth and more growth.
... Mbeki convinced Mandela that what
was needed was a definitive break with the past. The ANC needed
a completely new economic plan-something bold, something shocking,
something that would communicate, in the broad, dramatic strokes
the market understood, that the ANC was ready to embrace the Washington
Consensus.
... In June 1996, Mbeki unveiled the results:
it was a neoliberal shock therapy program for South Africa, calling
for more privatization, cutbacks to government spending, labor
"flexibility," freer trade and even looser controls
on money flows. According to GeIb, its overriding aim "was
to signal to potential investors the government's (and specifically
the ANC's) commitment to the prevailing orthodoxy." To make
sure the message was loud and clear to traders in New York and
London, at the public launch of the plan, Mbeki quipped, "Just
call me a Thatcherite."
p266
South Africa's Truth and Reconcillation Commission is frequently
held up as a model of successful "peace building," exported
to other conflict zones from Sri Lanka to Afghanistan. But many
of those who were directly involved in the process are deeply
ambivalent. When he unveiled the final report in March 2003, the
commission's chairman, Archbishop Desmond Tutu, confronted journalists
with freedom's unfinished business. "Can you explain how
a black person wakes up in a squalid ghetto today, almost 10 years
after freedom ?hen he goes to work in town, which is still largely
white, in palatial homes. And at the end of the day, he goes back
home to squalor? I don't know why those people don't just say,
'To hell with peace. To hell with Tutu and the truth commission."
[Yasmin] Sooka [one of the jurors on South
Africa's Truth and Reconciliation Commission] who now heads South
Africa's Foundation for Human Rights, says that she feels that
though the hearings dealt with what she described as "outward
manifestations of apartheid such as torture, severe ill treatment
and disappearances," it left the economic system served by
those abuses "completely untouched"-an echo of the concerns
about the blindness of "human rights" expressed by Orlando
Letelier three decades earlier. If she had the process to do over
again, Sooka said, "I would do it completely differently.
I would look at the systems of apartheid - I would look at the
question of land, I would certainly look at the role of multinationals,
I would look at the role of the mining industry very, very closely
because I think that's the real sickness of South Africa ....
I would look at the systematic effects of the policies of apartheid,
and I would devote only one hearing to torture because I think
when you focus on torture and you don't look at what it was serving,
that's when you start to do a revision of the real history."
p268
Then there is the matter of where, precisely, the money is going.
During the transition negotiations, F. W. de Klerk's team demanded
that all civil servants be guaranteed their jobs even after the
handover; those who wanted to leave, they argued, should receive
hefty lifelong pensions. This was an extraordinary demand in a
country with no social safety net to speak of, yet it was one
of several "technical" issues on which the ANC ceded
ground. The concession meant that the new ANC government carried
the cost of two governments-its own, and a shadow white government
that was out of power. Forty percent of the government's annual
debt payments go to the country's massive pension fund. The vast
majority of the beneficiaries are former apartheid employees.
In the end, South Africa has wound up
with a twisted case of reparations in reverse, with the white
businesses that reaped enormous profits from black labor during
the apartheid years paying not a cent in reparations, but the
victims of apartheid continuing to send large paychecks to their
former victimizers. And how do they raise the money for this generosity?
By stripping the state of its assets through privatization-a modern
form of the very looting that the ANC had been so intent on avoiding
when it agreed to negotiations, hoping to prevent a repeat of
Mozambique. Unlike what happened in Mozambique, however, where
civil servants broke machinery, stuffed their pockets and then
fled, in South Africa the dismantling of the state and the pillaging
of its coffers continue to this day.
p271
After more than a decade since South Africa made its decisive
turn toward Thatcherism, the results of its experiment in trickle-down
justice are scandalous:
*
Since 1994, the year the ANC took power, the number of people
living on less than $1 a day has doubled, from 2 million to 4
million in 2006 .
* Between 1991 and 2002, the unemployment
rate for black South Africans more than doubled, from 23 percent
to 48 percent.
* Of South Africa's 35 million black citizens,
only five thousand earn more than $60,000 a year. The number of
whites in that income bracket is twenty times higher, and many
earn far more than that amount.
* The ANC government has built 1.8 million
homes, but in the meantime 2 million people have lost their homes.
* Close to 1 million people have been
evicted from farms in the first decade of democracy.
* Such evictions have meant that the number
of shack dwellers has grown by 50 percent. In 2006, more than
one in four
* South Africans lived in shacks located
in informal shantytowns, many without running water or electricity.
p275
Grigory Gorin, Russian writer, 1993
For a Long time we lived under the dictatorship
of the Communists, but now we have found out that
life under the dictatorship of business people is no better.
p277
What happened next - the dissolution of the Soviet Union, Gorbachev's
eclipse by Yeltsin, and the tumultuous course of economic shock
therapy in Russia - one of the greatest crimes committed against
a democracy in modern history. Russia, like China, was forced
to choose between a Chicago School economic program and an authentic
democratic revolution. Faced with that choice, China's leaders
had attacked their own people in order to prevent democracy from
disturbing their free-market plans. Russia was different: the
democratic revolution was already well under way-in order to push
through a Chicago School economic program, that peaceful and hopeful
process that Gorbachev began had to be violently interrupted,
then radically reversed.
Gorbachev knew that the only way to impose
the kind of shock therapy being advocated by the G7 and the IMF
was with force-as did many in the West pushing for these policies.
The Economist magazine, in an influential 1990 piece, urged Gorbachev
to adopt "strongman rule... to smash the resistance that
has blocked serious economic reform." Only two weeks after
the Nobel Committee had declared an end to the Cold War, The Economist
was urging Gorbachev to model himself after one of the Cold War's
most notorious killers. Under the heading "Mikhail Sergeevich
Pinochet?" the article concluded that even though following
its advice could cause "possible blood-letting... it might,
just might, be the Soviet Union's turn for what could be called
the Pinochet approach to liberal economics." The Wash was
willing to go further. In August 1991, the paper ran a commentary
under the headline "Pinochet's Chile a Pragmatic Model for
Soviet Economy." The article supported the idea of a coup
for getting rid of the slow-going Gorbachev, but the author, Michael
Schrage, worried that the Soviet president's opponents "had
neither the savvy nor the support to seize the Pinochet option."
They should model themselves, Schrage wrote, after "a despot
who really knew how to run a coup: retired Chilean general Augusto
Pinochet."
Gorbachev soon found himself facing an
adversary who was more than willing to play the role of a Russian
Pinochet.
p281
Russian newspaper Nezavisirnaya Gazeta about Boris Yeltsin's government,
1991
For the first time Russia will get in
its government a team of liberals who consider themselves followers
of Friedrich von Hayek and the 'Chicago school' of Milton Friedman...
It will come as no surprise if they attempt to construct something
like a homegrown Pinochet system. in which the role of the 'Chicago
boys' will be played Yegor Gaidar's team.
p282
Vladimir Mau, an adviser to Boris Yeltsin
The most favorable condition for reform
[is a] weary public, exhausted by the previous political struggle
.... That is why the government was confident, on the eve of price
liberalization, that a drastic social clash was impossible, that
the government would not be overthrown by a popular revolt.
p283
After only one year [under Yeltsin], shock therapy had taken a
devastating toll: millions of middle-class Russians had lost their
life savings when money lost its value, and abrupt cuts to subsidies
meant millions of workers had not been paid in months. The average
Russian consumed 40 percent less in 1992 than in 1991, and a third
of the population fell below the poverty line. The middle class
was forced to sell personal belongings from card tables on the
streets - desperate acts that the Chicago School economists praised
as "entrepreneurial".
p286
... Yeltsin, confident that he had the West's support, took his
first irreversible step toward what was now being openly referred
to as the "Pinochet option": he issued decree 1400,
announcing that the constitution was abolished and parliament
dissolved. Two days later, a special session of parliament voted
636-2 to impeach Yeltsin for this outrageous act (the equivalent
of the U.S. president unilaterally dissolving Congress). Vice
President Aleksandr Rutskoi announced that Russia had already
"paid a dear price for the political adventurism" of
Yeltsin and the reformers.
Some kind of armed conflict between Yeltsin
and the parliament was now inevitable. Despite the fact that Russia's
Constitutional Court once again ruled Yeltsin's behavior unconstitutional,
Clinton continued to back him, and Congress voted to give Yeltsin
$2.5 billion in aid. Emboldened, Yeltsin sent in troops to surround
the parliament and got the city to cut off power, heat and phone
lines to the White House parliament building. Boris Kagarlitsky,
director of the Institute of Globalization Studies in Moscow,
told me that supporters of Russian democracy "were coming
in by the thousands trying to break the blockade. There were two
weeks of peaceful demonstrations confronting the troops and police
forces, which led to partial unblocking of the parliament building,
with people able to bring food and water inside. Peaceful resistance
was growing more popular and gaining broader support every day."
With each side becoming more entrenched,
the only compromise that could have resolved the standoff would
have been for both sides to agree to early elections, putting
everybody's job up for public review. Many were urging this outcome,
but just as Yeltsin was weighing his options, and reportedly leaning
toward elections, news came from Poland that voters had rained
down their decisive punishment on Solidarity, the party that had
betrayed them with shock therapy.
After they witnessed Solidarity get pounded
at the polls, it was obvious to Yeltsin and his Western advisers
that early elections were far too risky. In Russia, too much wealth
hung in the balance: huge oil fields, about 30 percent of the
world's natural gas reserves, 20 percent of its nickel, not to
mention weapons factories and the state media apparatus with which
the Communist Party had controlled the vast population.
Yeltsin abandoned negotiations and moved
into war posture. Having just doubled military salaries, he had
most of the army on his side, and he "surrounded the parliament
with thousands of Interior Ministry troops, barbed wire and water
cannons and refused to let anyone pass," according to The
Washington Post. Vice President Rutskoi, Yeltsin's main rival
in parliament, had by this point armed his guards and welcomed
proto-fascist nationalists into his camp. He urged his supporters
to "not give a moment of peace" to Yeltsin's "dictatorship.
Kagarlitsky, who participated in the protests and wrote a book
about the episode, told me that on October 3, crowds of supporters
of the parliament "marched to the Ostankino TV center to
demand that news be announced. Some people in the crowd were armed,
but most were not. There were children in the crowd. It was met
by Yeltsin's troops and machine-gunned." About one hundred
demonstrators, and one member of the military, were killed. Yeltsin's
next move was to dissolve all city and regional councils in the
country. Russia's young democracy was being destroyed piece by
piece.
There is no doubt that some parliamentarians
showed antipathy for a peaceful settlement by egging on the crowds,
but as even the former U.S. State Department official Leslie Gelb
wrote, the parliament was "not dominated by a bunch of right-wing
crazies." It was Yeltsin's illegal dissolution of parliament
and his defiance of the country's highest court that precipitated
the crisis-moves that were bound to be met by desperate measures
in a country that had little desire to give up the democracy it
had just won.
A clear signal from Washington or the
EU could have forced Yeltsin to engage in serious negotiations
with the parliamentarians, but he received only encouragement.
Finally, on the morning of October 4, 1993, Yeltsin fulfilled
his long-prescribed destiny and became Russia's very own Pinochet,
unleashing a series of violent events with unmistakable echoes
of the coup in Chile exactly twenty years earlier. In what was
the third traumatic shock inflicted by Yeltsin on the Russian
people, he ordered a reluctant army to storm the Russian White
House, setting it on fire and leaving charred the very building
he had built his reputation defending just two years earlier.
Communism may have collapsed without the firing of a single shot,
but Chicago-style capitalism, it turned out, required a great
deal of gunfire to defend itself: Yeltsin called in five thousand
soldiers, dozens of tanks and armored personnel carriers, helicopters
and elite shock troops armed with automatic machine guns-all to
defend Russia's new capitalist economy from the grave threat of
democracy.
p291
In practice, the Communist state was simply replaced with a corporatist
one: the beneficiaries of the boom were confined to a small club
of Russians, many of them former Communist Party apparatchiks,
and a handful of Western mutual fund managers who made dizzying
returns investing in newly privatized Russian companies. A clique
of nouveaux billionaires, many of whom were to become part of
the group universally known as "the oligarchs" for their
imperial levels of wealth and power, teamed up with Yeltsin's
Chicago Boys and stripped the country of nearly everything of
value, moving the enormous profits offshore at a rate of $2 billion
a month. Before shock therapy, Russia! had no millionaires; by
2003, the number of Russian billionaires had risen to seventeen,
according to the Forbes list.
p292
For the country's oligarchs and foreign investors, only one cloud
loomed on the horizon: Yeltsin's plummeting popularity. The effects
of the economic program were so brutal for the average Russian,
and the process was so self-evidently corrupt, that his approval
ratings fell to the single digits.
... In December 1994, Yeltsin did what
so many desperate leaders L have done throughout history to hold
on to power: he started a war. His national security chief, Oleg
Lobov, had confided to a legislator, {We need a small, victorious
war to raise the president's ratings," and the defense minister
predicted that his army could defeat the forces in the breakaway
republic of Chechnya in a matter of hours -a cakewalk.
p292
When Yeltsin faced reelection in 1996, he was still so unpopular
and his defeat looked so certain that his advisers toyed with
canceling the vote altogether; a letter signed by a group of Russian
bankers published in all the Russian national newspapers strongly
hinted at this possibility. Yeltsin's privatization minister,
Anatoly Chubais (whom Sachs once described as "a freedom
fighter"), became one of the most outspoken proponents of
the Pinochet option. In order to have a democracy in society there
must be a dictatorship in power," he pronounced. It was a
direct echo of both the excuses made for Pinochet by Chile's Chicago
Boys and Deng Xiaoping's philosophy of Friedmanism without the
freedom.
In the end, the election went ahead and
Yeltsin won, thanks to an estimated $100 million in financing
from oligarchs (thirty-three times the legal amount) as well as
eight hundred times more coverage on oligarch-controlled TV stations
than his rivals. With the threat of a sudden change in government
removed, the knockoff Chicago Boys were able to move to the most
contentious, and most lucrative, part of their program: selling
off what Lenin had once called "the commanding heights."
Forty percent of an oil company comparable
in size to France's Total was sold for $88 million (Total's sales
in 2006 were $193 billion). Norilsk Nickel, which produced a fifth
of the world's nickel, was sold for $170 million-even though its
profits alone soon reached $1.5 billion annually. The massive
oil company Yukos, which controls more oil than Kuwait, was sold
for $309 million; it now earns more than $3 billion in revenue
a year. Fifty-one percent of the oil giant Sidanko went for $130
million; just two years later that stake would be valued on the
international market at $2.8 billion. A huge weapons factory sold
for $3 million, the price of a vacation home in Aspen.
The scandal wasn't just that Russia's
public riches were auctioned off for a fraction of their worth-it
was also that, in true corporatist style, they were purchased
with public money. As the Moscow Times journalists Malt Bivens
and Jonas Bernstein put it, "a few hand-picked men took over
Russia's state-developed oil fields for free, as part of a giant
shell game in which one arm of government paid another arm."
In a bold act of cooperation between the politicians selling the
public companies and the businessmen buying them, several of Yeltsin's
ministers transferred large sums of public money, which should
have gone into the national bank or treasury, into private banks
that had been hastily incorporated by oligarchs.* The state then
contracted with the same banks to run the privatization auctions
for the oil fields and mines. The banks ran the auctions, but
they also bid in them-and sure enough, the oligarch-owned banks
decided to make themselves the proud new owners of the previously
public assets. The money that they put up to buy the shares in
these public companies was likely the same public money that Yeltsin's
ministers had deposited with them earlier. In other words, the
Russian people fronted the money for the looting of their own
country.
p299
In the absence of major famine, plague or battle, never have so
many lost so much in such a short period of time. By 1998, more
than 80 percent of Russian farms had gone bankrupt, and roughly
seventy thousand state factories had closed, creating an epidemic
of unemployment. In 1989, before shock therapy, 2 million people
in the Russian Federation were living in poverty, on less than
$4 a day. By the time the shock therapists had administered their
"bitter medicine" in the mid-nineties, 74 million Russians
were living below the poverty line, according to the World Bank.
That means that Russia's "economic reforms" can claim
credit for the impoverishment of 72 million people in only eight
years. By 1996, 25 percent of Russians - almost 37 million people-lived
in poverty described as "desperate."
Although millions of Russians have been
pulled out of poverty in recent years, thanks largely to soaring
oil and gas prices, Russia's underclass of extreme poor has remained
permanent-with all the sicknesses associated with that discarded
status.
p301
Russia's population is ... in dramatic decline-the country is
losing roughly 700,000 people a year. Between 1992, the first
full year of shock therapy, and 2006, Russia's population shrank
by 6.6 million. Three decades ago, André Gunder Frank,
the dissident Chicago economist, wrote a letter to Milton Friedman
accusing him of "economic genocide." Many Russians describe
the slow disappearance of their fellow citizens in similar terms
today.
... This planned misery is made all the
more grotesque because the wealth accumulated by the elite is
flaunted in Moscow as nowhere else outside of a handful of oil
emirates. In Russia today, wealth is so stratified that the rich
and the poor seem to be living not only in different countries
but in different centuries. One time zone is downtown Moscow,
transformed in fast-forward into a futuristic twenty-first-century
sin city, where oligarchs race around in black Mercedes convoys,
guarded by top-of-the-line mercenary soldiers, and where Western
money managers are seduced by the open investment rules by day
and by on-the-house prostitutes by night In the other time zone,
a seventeen-year-old provincial girl, asked about her hopes for
the future, replied, "It's difficult to talk about the twenty-first
century when you're sitting here reading by candlelight. The twenty-first
century does not matter. It's the nineteenth century here."
p302
For both the Clinton and Bush Sr. administrations, not to mention
the European Union, the G7 and the IMF, the clear goal in Russia
was to erase the preexisting state and create the conditions for
a capitalist feeding frenzy, which in turn would kick-start a
booming free-market democracy-managed by overconfident Americans
barely out of school. In other words, it was Iraq without the
explosives.
When the zeal for shock therapy in Russia
was at its peak, its cheerleaders were absolutely convinced that
only total destruction of every single institution would create
the conditions for a national rebirth - the dream of the blank
slate that would recur in Baghdad. It is "desirable,"
wrote the Harvard historian Richard Pipes, "for Russia to
keep on disintegrating until nothing remains of its institutional
structures." And the Columbia University economist Richard
Ericson wrote in 1995, "Any reform must be disruptive on
a historically unprecedented scale. An entire world must be discarded,
including all of its economic and most of its social and political
institutions, and concluding with the physical structure of production,
capital, and technology.
Another Iraq parallel: no matter how baldly
Yeltsin defied anything resembling democracy, his rule was still
characterized in the West as part of "a transition to democracy,"
a narrative that would change only when Putin began cracking down
on the illegal activities of several of the oligarchs. Similarly,
the Bush administration has always portrayed Iraq as on the road
to freedom, even in the face of overwhelming evidence of rampant
torture, out-of-control death squads and pervasive press censorship.
Russia's economic program was always described as "reform,"
just as Iraq is perennially under "reconstruction,"
even after the U.S. contractors have mostly all fled, leaving
the infrastructure in a shambles, as the destruction roars on.
In Russia in the mid-nineties, anyone who dared question the wisdom
of "the reformers" was dismissed as nostalgic for Stalin,
just as critics of Iraq's occupation were, for years, met with
accusations that they thought life was better under Saddam Hussein.
p304
The entire thirty-year history of he Chicago School experiment
has been one of mass corruption and corporatist collusion between
security states and large corporations, from Chile's piranhas,
to Argentina's crony privatizations, to Russia's oligarchs, to
Enron's energy shell game, to Iraq's "free fraud zone."
The point of shock therapy is to open up a window for enormous
profits to be made very quickly-not despite the lawlessness but
precisely because of it.
p304
The movement that Milton Friedman launched in the 1950s is best
understood as an attempt by multinational capital to recapture
the highly profitable, lawless frontier that Adam Smith, the intellectual
forefather of today's neoliberals, so admired -but with a twist.
Rather than journeying through Smith's "savage and barbarous
nations" where there was no Western law (no longer a practical
option), this movement set out to systematically dismantle existing
laws and regulations to re-create that earlier lawlessness. And
where Smith's colonists earned their record profits by seizing
what he described as "waste lands" for "but a trifle,"
today's multinationals see government programs, public assets
and everything that is not for sale as terrain to be conquered
and seized-the post office, national parks, schools, social security,
disaster relief and anything else that is publicly administered.
Under Chicago School economics, the state
acts as the colonial frontier, which corporate conquistadors pillage
with the same ruthless determination and energy as their predecessors
showed when they hauled home the gold and silver of the Andes.
Where Smith saw fertile green fields turned into profitable farmlands
on the pampas and the prairies, Wall Street saw "green field
opportunities" in Chile's phone system, Argentina's airline,
Russia's oil fields, Bolivia's water system, the United States'
public airwaves, Poland's factories-all built with public wealth,
then sold for a trifle.
p308
In much of the Southern Hemisphere, neoliberalism is frequently
spoken of as "the second colonial pillage": in the first
pillage, the riches were seized from the land, and in the second
they were stripped from the state. After every one of these profit
frenzies come the promises: next time, there will be firm laws
in place before a country's assets are sold off, and the entire
process will be watched over by eagle-eyed regulators and investigators
with unimpeachable ethics. Next time there will be "institution
building" before privatizations (to use the post-Russia parlance).
But calling for law and order after the profits have all been
moved offshore is really just a way of legalizing the theft ex
post facto, much as the European colonizers locked in their land
grabs with treaties.
p318
There was never going to be a Marshall Plan for Russia because
there was only ever a Marshall Plan because of Russia. When Yeltsin
abolished the Soviet Union, the "loaded gun" that had
forced the development of the original plan was disarmed. Without
it, capitalism was suddenly free to lapse into its most savage
form, not just in Russia but around the world. With the Soviet
collapse, the free market now had a global monopoly, which meant
all the "distortions" that had been interfering with
its perfect equilibrium were no longer required.
... This liberation from all constraints
is, in essence, Chicago School economics (otherwise known as neoliberalism
or, in the U.S., neoconservatism): not some new invention but
capitalism stripped of its Keynesian appendages, capitalism in
its monopoly phase, a system that has let itself go-that no longer
has to work to keep us as customers, that can be as antisocial,
antidemocratic and boorish as-it wants. As long as Communism was
a threat, the gentlemen's agreement that was Keynesianism would
live on; once that system lost ground, all traces of compromise
could finally be eradicated, thereby fulfilling the purist goal
Friedman had set out for his movement a half century earlier.
p323
John Williamson, economist, at a conference of Milton Friedman
/ University of Chicago doctrine proponents, in Washington, DC,
January 13, 1995
One will have to ask whether it could
conceivably make sense to think of deliberately provoking a crisis
so as to remove the political logjam to [economic] reform.
p327
... At Washington's most powerful financial institutions ... there
was a willingness not only to create an appearance of crisis through
the media but also to take concrete measures to generate crises
that were all too real.
p328
The Chicago School crisis addicts were certainly on a speedy intellectual
trajectory. Only a few years earlier, they had speculated that
a hyperinflation crisis could create the shocking conditions required
for shock policies. Now a chief economist at the World Bank, an
institution funded, by this time, with tax dollars from 178 countries
and whose mandate was to rebuild and strengthen struggling economies,
was advocating the creation of failed states because of the opportunities
they provided to start over in the rubble.
p328
Davidson Budhoo was a Grenadian-born, London School of Economics-trained
economist ... [who] had worked at the IMF for twelve years, where
is job was designing structural adjustment programs or Africa,
Latin America and his native Caribbean. After the organization
took its sharp right turn during the Reagan/Thatcher era, the
independent-minded Budhoo felt increasingly ill at ease in his
place of work. The fund was packed with zealous Chicago Boys under
the leadership of its managing director, the staunch neoliberal
Michel Camdessus. When Budhoo quit in 1988, he decided to devote
himself to exposing the secrets of his former workplace. It began
when he wrote a remarkable open letter to Camdessus ...
... Today I resigned from the staff of
the International Monetary Fund after over twelve years, and after
1000 days of official Fund work in the field, hawking your medicine
and your bag of tricks to governments and to peoples in Latin
America and the Caribbean and Africa. To me resignation is a priceless
liberation, for with it I have taken the first big step to that
place where I may hope to wash my hands of what in my mind's eye
is the blood of millions of poor and starving peoples .... The
blood is so much, you know, it runs in rivers. It dries up, too;
it cakes all over me; sometimes I feel that there is not enough
soap in the whole world to cleanse me from the things that I did
do in your name."
... governments and peoples [are] forced
to bend on their knees before us, broken and terrified and disintegrating,
and begging for a sliver of reasonableness and decency on our
part. But we laugh cruelly in their face, and the torture goes
on unabated."
p336
Back in the early nineties, whenever advocates of free trade wanted
a persuasive success story to invoke in debates, they invariably
pointed to the Asian Tigers. These were the miracle economies
that were growing by leaps and bounds, supposedly because they
had flung open their borders to unrestricted globalization. It
was a useful story - the Tigers were certainly developing with
whirlwind speed - but to suggest that their expansion was based
on free trade was fiction. Malaysia, South Korea and Thailand
still had highly protectionist policies that barred foreigners
from owning land and from buying out national firms. They had
also maintained a significant role for the state, keeping sectors
like energy and transportation in public hands. The Tigers had
also blocked many foreign imports from Japan, Europe and North
America, as they built up their own domestic markets. They were
economic success stories unquestionably, but ones that proved
that mixed, managed economies grew faster and more equitably than
those following the Wild West Washington Consensus.
The situation did not please Western and
Japanese investment banks and multinational firms; watching Asia's
consumer market explode, they understandably longed for unfettered
access to the region to sell their products. They also wanted
the right to buy up the best of the Tigers' corporations-particularly
Korea's impressive conglomerates like Daewoo, Hyundai, Samsung
and LG. In the mid-nineties, under pressure from the IMF and the
newly created World Trade Organization, Asian governments agreed
to split the difference: they would maintain the laws that protected
national firms from foreign ownership and resist pressure to privatize
their key state companies, but they would lift barriers to their
financial sectors, allowing a surge of paper investing and currency
trading.
In 1997, when the flood of hot money suddenly
reversed current in Asia, it was a direct result of this kind
of speculative investment, which was legalized only because of
Western pressure. Wall Street, of course, didn't see it that way.
Top investment analysts instantly recognized the crisis as the
chance to level the remaining barriers protecting Asia's markets
once and for all. Pelosky, the Morgan Stanley strategist, was
particularly forthright about the logic: if the crisis was left
to worsen, all foreign currency would be drained from the region
and Asian-owned companies would have either to close down or to
sell themselves to Western firms-both beneficial outcomes for
Morgan Stanley. "I'd like to see closure of companies and
asset sales .... sales are very difficult; typically owners don't
want to sell unless they're forced to. Therefore, we need more
bad news to continue to put the pressure on these corporates to
sell their companies."
Some saw the breaking of Asia in even
grander terms. José Piflera, Pinochet's star minister who
was now working at the Cato Institute in Washington, D.C., greeted
the crisis with undisguised glee, pronouncing that "the day
of reckoning has arrived." In Piflera's eyes, the crisis
was the latest chapter in the war that he and his fellow Chicago
Boys had started in Chile in the seventies. The fall of the Tigers,
he said, represented nothing less than "the fall of a second
Berlin Wall," the collapse of "the notion that there
is a 'Third Way' between free-market democratic capitalism and
socialist statism."
Piflera's was not a fringe perspective.
It was openly shared by Alan Greenspan, chairman of the U.S. Federal
Reserve and probably the single most powerful economic policy
maker in the world. Greenspan described the crisis as "a
very dramatic event towards a consensus of the type of market
system which we have in this country." He also observed that
"the current crisis is likely to accelerate the dismantling
in many Asian countries of the remnants of a system with large
elements of government-directed investment." 15 In other
words, the destruction of Asia's managed economy was actually
a process of creating a new American-style economy-birth pangs
for a new Asia, to borrow a phrase that would be used in an even
more violent context a few years later.
...
Eager not to let this opportunity slip by, the IMF-after months
doing nothing while the emergency worsened-finally entered into
negotiations with the ailing governments of Asia. The only country
to resist the fund in this period was Malaysia, thanks to its
relatively small debt. Malaysia's controversial prime minister,
Mahthir Mohammad said that he did not think he should have to
"destroy the economy in order that it should become better,"
which was enough to brand him as a raving radical at the time.
The rest of Asia's crisis-struck economies were too desperate
for foreign currency to refuse the possibility of tens of billions
in IMF loans: Thailand, the Philippines, Indonesia and South Korea
all came to the table. "You can't force a country to ask
you for help. It has to ask. But when it's out of money, it hasn't
got many places to turn," said Stanley Fischer, who was in
charge of the talks for the IMF.
Fischer had been one of the most vocal
advocates of shock therapy in Russia, and despite the harrowing
human costs there, his attitude was just as unyielding in Asia.
Several governments suggested that since the crisis was caused
by the ease with which money could gush in and out of their countries
with nothing to slow down the flow, perhaps it made sense to put
some barriers back up-the dreaded "capital controls."
China had kept its controls up (ignoring Friedman's advice in
this regard), and it was the only country in the region that was
not being ravaged by the crisis. And Malaysia had put controls
back up, and they seemed to be working.
Fischer and the rest of the IMF team dismissed
the idea out of hand. The IMF displayed no interest in what had
actually caused the crisis. Instead, like a prison interrogator
looking for a weakness, the fund was exclusively focused on how
the crisis could be used as leverage. The meltdown had forced
a group of strong-willed countries to beg for mercy; to fail to
take advantage of that window of opportunity was, for the Chicago
School economists running the IMF, tantamount to professional
negligence.
With their treasuries empty, the Tigers
were, as far as the IMF was concerned, broken; now they were primed
to be remade. The first stage of this process was to strip the
countries of all the "trade and investment protectionism
and activist state intervention that were the key ingredients
of the 'Asian miracle," as the political scientist Walden
Bello put it." The IMF also demanded that the governments
make deep budget cuts, leading to mass layoffs of public sector
workers in countries where people were already taking their own
lives in record numbers. Fischer admitted after the fact that
the IMF had concluded that in Korea and Indonesia, the crisis
was unrelated to government overspending. Nonetheless, he used
the extraordinary leverage granted by the crisis to extract these
painful austerity measures. As one New York Times reporter wrote,
the IMF's actions were "like a heart surgeon who, in the
middle of an operation, decides to do some work on the lungs and
kidneys, too."
After the IMF had stripped the Tigers
of their old habits and ways, they were now ready to be reborn,
Chicago-style: privatized basic services, independent central
banks, "flexible" workforces, low social spending and,
of course, total free trade.
... The economic meltdown was so dire
that it gave governments the license (as similar crises had from
Bolivia to Russia) to declare temporary authoritarian rule; it
didn't last long - just long enough to impose the IMF decrees.
... As far as the IMF was concerned, the
crisis was going extremely well. In less than a year, it had negotiated
the economic equivalent of extreme makeovers for Thailand, Indonesia,
South Korea and the Philippines.
p344
The human costs of the IMF's opportunism were nearly as devastating
in Asia as in Russia. The International Labor Organization estimates
that a staggering 24 million people lost their jobs in this period
and that Indonesia's unemployment rate increased from 4 to 12
percent. Thailand was losing 2,000 jobs a day at the height of
the "reforms"- 60,000 a month. In South Korea, 300,000
workers were fired every month - largely the result of the IMF's
totally unnecessary demands to slash government budgets and hike
interest rates. By 1999, South Korea's and Indonesia's unemployment
rates had nearly tripled in only two years. As in Latin America
in the seventies, what disappeared in these parts of Asia was
what was so remarkable about the region's "miracle"
in the first place: its large and growing middle class. In 1996,
63.7 percent of South Koreans identified as middle class; by 1999
that number was down to 38.4 percent. According to the World Bank,
20 million Asians were thrown into poverty in this period of what
Rodolfo Walsh would have called "planned misery.
... while the IMF certainly failed the
people of Asia, it did not fail Wall Street-far from it. The hot
money may have been spooked by the IMF's drastic measures, but
the large investment houses and multinational firms were emboldened.
"Of course these markets are highly volatile," said
Jerome Booth, head of research at London's Ashmore Investment
Management. "That's what makes them fun." These fun-seeking
firms understood that as a result of the IMF adjustments,"
pretty much everything in Asia was now up for sale-and the more
the market panicked, the more desperate Asian companies would
be to sell, pushing their prices through the floor. Morgan Stanley's
Jay Pelosky had said that what Asia needed was "more bad
news to continue to put pressure on these corporates to sell their
companies"-and that's exactly what happened, thanks to the
IMF.
... Within two years, the face of much
of Asia was utterly transformed, with hundreds of local brands
replaced by multinational giants. It was dubbed "the world's
biggest going-out-of-business sale," by The New York Times,
and a "business-buying bazaar" by BusinessWeek.
... All told, there were 186 major mergers
and acquisitions of firms in Indonesia, Thailand, South Korea,
Malaysia and the Philippines by foreign multinationals in a span
of only twenty months. Watching this sale unfold, Robert Wade,
an LSE economist, and Frank Veneroso, an economic consultant,
predicted that the IMF program "may even precipitate the
biggest peacetime transfer of assets from domestic to foreign
owners in the past fifty years anywhere in the world.
... Milton Friedman, at the height of
the crisis, had cautioned against panic, insisting that "it
will be over .... As they get this financial mess settled, you
can see a return to growth in Asia, but whether it will be one
year, two years, three years, nobody can tell you."
... The ugly secret of "stabilization"
is that the vast majority, never climb back aboard. They end up
in slums, now home to 1 billion people; they end up in brothels
or in cargo ship containers.
p351
Free-market crusaders are, however, slow learners when it comes
to the unintended consequences of their policies. The only lesson
learned from the enormously lucrative Asian sell-off appears to
have been yet more confirmation for the shock doctrine, more evidence
(as if any more was needed) that there is nothing like a true
disaster, a genuine churning of society, to open up a new frontier.
A few years after the peak of the crisis, several prominent commentators
were even willing to go so far as to say that what happened in
Asia, despite all the devastation, was a blessing in disguise.
The Economist noted that "it took a national crisis for South
Korea to turn from an inward-looking nation to one that embraced
foreign capital, change and competition." And Thomas Friedman,
in his best-selling book The Lexus and the Olive Tree, declared
that what happened in Asia wasn't a crisis at all. "I believe
globalization did us all a favor by melting down the economies
of Thailand, Korea, Malaysia, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia, and Brazil
in the 1990s, because it laid bare a lot of rotten practices and
institution he wrote, adding that "exposing the crony capitalism
in Korea was no crisis in my book. In his New York Times columns
supporting the invasion of Iraq, a similar logic would be on display,
except that the melting down would be done with cruise missiles,
not currency trades.
p352
Financial Times editorial
... Asia was a "warning signal that
public unease with capitalism and the forces of globalization
is reaching a worrying level. The Asian crisis showed the world
how even the most successful countries could be brought to their
knees by a sudden outflow of capital. People were outraged at
how the whims of secretive hedge funds could apparently cause
mass poverty on the other side of the world.
p352
Unlike in the former Soviet Union, where the planned misery o
shock therapy could be passed off as part of the "painful
transition" from Communism to market democracy, Asia's crisis
was plainly a creation of the global markets. Yet when the high
priests of globalization sent missions to the disaster zone, all
they wanted to do was deepen the pain.
p352
After 1998, it became increasingly difficult to impose the shock
therapy-style makeovers by peaceful means-through the usual IMF
bullying or arm-twisting at trade summits. The defiant new mood
coming from the South made its global debut when the World Trade
Organization talks collapsed in Seattle in 1999. Though the college-age
protesters received the bulk of the media coverage, the real rebellion
took place inside the conference center, when developing countries
formed a voting bloc and rejected demands for deeper trade concessions
as long as Europe and the U.S. continued to subsidize and protect
their domestic industries.
At the time, it was still possible to
dismiss the Seattle breakdown as a minor pause in the steady advance
of corporatism. Within a few years, however, the depth of the
shift would be undeniable: the U.S. government's ambitious dream
of creating a unified free-trade zone encompassing all of Asia-Pacific
was abandoned, as were a global investors' treaty and plans for
a Free Trade Area of the Americas, stretching from Alaska to Chile.
Perhaps the greatest impact of the so-called
antiglobalization movement was that it forced the Chicago School
ideology into the dead center of the international debate. For
a brief moment at the turn of the millennium, there was no pressing
crisis to deflect attention-the debt shocks had faded, the "transitions"
were complete, and a new global war had not yet arrived. What
was left was the real world track record of the free-market crusade:
the dismal reality of inequality, corruption and environmental
degradation left behind when government after government embraced
Friedman's advice, given to Pinochet all those years ago, that
it was a mistake to try "to do good with other people's money."
In retrospect, it is striking that capitalism's
monopoly period, when it no longer had to deal with competing
ideas or counterpowers, was extremely brief-only eight years,
from the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991 to the collapse
of the WTO talks in 1999.
The Shock Doctrine
Home Page