Trends in Civil Society
excerpted from the book
The New Progressive Era
Toward a Fair and Deliberative
Democracy
by Peter Levine
Rowman and Littlefield, 2000,
paper
p75
Only by cooperating can ordinary citizens put much pressure on
the government: thus associational life is a source of political
power that can partially counterbalance the influence of money.
To the extent that people cooperate voluntarily, they do not have
to legislate or litigate to solve their problems, so they can
reserve their political energies for necessarily contentious issues.
And citizens who participate in voluntary associations may develop
a moral concern for others, a public-spiritedness that is normally
cultivated neither by private economic behavior nor by solitary
voting. Both the political system and the market are intensely
competitive. Cooperation occurs much more easily in the sphere
of civil society; and once people have cooperated as members of
a voluntary group, they may be less antagonistic in the political
realm.
p77
... the rate of union membership in the United States (less than
9 percent of adults) is paltry compared to that in some other
industrialized democracies.
p78
Church-based associations account for the relative strength of
civil society in the United States. They have attracted almost
half of the U.S. population, compared to just 13 percent of people
in the average industrialized democracy.
p78
Fundamentalist Denominations
Fundamentalist denominations are no exception.
They aggressively recruit people of all backgrounds and motivate
them to participate politically. Since most evangelical churches
are managed by lay people, they are especially likely to offer
their members political experience and to cultivate strong interpersonal
ties. For example, as part of their church activities, Baptists
are much more likely to plan meetings and make presentations than
Catholics are. (Not all Baptists are fundamentalists, but all
fundamentalists belong to Protestant denominations that teach
civic skills.) It is true that fundamentalists join considerably
fewer groups than people who call themselves religious moderates
or liberals do. They are also less likely to vote, to trust other
people, and to read a daily newspaper. However, fundamentalists
have lower-than-average family incomes. If we control for income,
most of the differences between fundamentalists and religious
moderates and liberals disappear. For example, adjusting for income,
fundamentalists belong to about the same number of associations
as average Americans do and are actually more likely to vote in
some years.
Although fundamentalist denominations
build communities of mutual support, they also promote suspicion
of outsiders. However, political participation does not suffer
as a result. If anything, people seem to be motivated to vote
by a belief that many of their compatriots are immoral. In short,
the results of successful evangelization probably include more
civic participation by some poor and low-status people, but also
more generalized distrust and ideological division.
p81
The proportion of people who agree that "You can trust the
government in Washington to do what is right just about always,
or most of the time" has fallen from 72 percent in 1960 to
about 22 percent today. This decline has been continuous except
for a modest rebound during the Reagan years...
Finally, reported trust in the press has
plummeted in recent years. The proportion of Americans who said
that they had "a great deal of confidence" in television
news dropped from 55 percent in 1988 to 25 percent in 1993. In
the same period, confidence in newspapers fell from 50 percent
to 20 percent, and confidence in magazines declined from 38 percent
to 12 percent. Only 10 percent of Americans now say they have
"a great deal of confidence" in the press overall (down
from 29 percent in 1976).
p84
Since residential segregation by wealth is growing, many middle-income
Americans no longer live near those who are most likely to commit
violent crimes: the poor. Furthermore, those who can afford private
security services prefer to spend money protecting themselves,
rather than fighting crime in their broader communities. This
is economically rational policy: why act as an unpaid crime-fighter
in a potentially dangerous neighborhood when you can move far
away from most of the potential lawbreakers? And why pay taxes
for police and schools when you can hire a specialist to keep
criminals away from your house? In fact, three times as many people
are now employed by private protective services as by police forces;
and private security consumes $52 billion a year, 73 percent more
than public law enforcement (up from 57 percent more in 1980).
As the National Institute of Justice reported in 1990, "Private
security is now clearly the nation's primary protective resource."
p84
The epitome of suburban life may be a development like Bear Creek
in Washington State, where "there are no pesky doorbellers,
be they politicians or Girl Scouts.... A random encounter is the
last thing people want here. There is a new park, every blade
of grass in shape-but for members only. Four private security
guards man the entrance gates 24 hours a day, keeping the residents
of Bear Creek in a nearly crime-free bubble. And should a dog
try to stray outside its yard, the pet would be instantly zapped
by an electronic monitor." Bear Creek is a civil society:
a well-ordered, nongovernmental association. Residents probably
trust one another; they certainly share resources and delegate
impressive powers to their community association. However, Bear
Creek is exclusive and inward-looking; its walls signify a deep
mistrust of the society beyond. About four million Americans now
live in "gated communities."
p85
Furthermore, any given type of broadcast may change over time.
Between 1988 and 1995, "the number of minutes devoted to
crime on the nightly news" quintupled. Crime reporting has
fallen since 1995, but a third of the average local news broadcast
is still devoted to it. In a community of several million people,
there may be a heinous outrage every week, even if the crime rate
is low. The worse the horror, the more we can expect the television
news to give us a riveting, prurient, vicarious experience of
it. A decline in interpersonal trust seems almost predictable
under these circumstances. Summarizing various studies, Putnam
concludes that "heavy watchers of TV are unusually skeptical
about the benevolence of other people-overestimating crime rates,
for example."
p87
In January 1996, the Washington Post published a lead article
to announce the results of an extensive poll. The headline proclaimed,
"Who's in Control? Many Don't Know or Care." Indeed,
only 52 percent of respondents could say correctly whether the
Democrats or the Republicans were the more conservative party;
about a third could name their U.S. representative; 27 percent
were aware (or guessed) that the federal government spent more
on Medicare than foreign aid, and 6 percent could name the chief
justice. People who knew a great deal were likely to vote, no
matter how interested they were in politics. But those with little
`) knowledge generally believed that they were powerless-and abstained
from voting. If they did vote, their choices at the polls were
so unconnected to their stated priorities that "it was as
if their vote was random," according to Michael Delli Carpini,
a political scientist.
Anyone who was alarmed by these findings
would have been further distressed when fewer than half of eligible
adults voted in the 1996 elections, the lowest turnout in a presidential
election since 1924. Nor did matters improve in 1998, when participation
was the worst in an off-year election since 1942, and a record
number of citizens did not vote. The United States always has
extremely low: levels of participation compared to other countries;
only Switzerland is obviously worse among the industrialized democracies.
p88
... public ignorance and alienation have been the topics of debate
since at least the Progressive Era, when Lippmann gathered anecdotal
information and concluded:
The random collection of bystanders who
constitute a public could not, even if they had a mind to intervene
in all the problems of the day. They can and must play a part
occasionally, I believe, but they cannot take an interest in,
they cannot make even the coarsest judgments about, and they will
not act even in the most grossly partisan way on, all the questions
arising daily in a complex and changing society. Normally, they
leave their proxies to a kind of professional public consisting
of more or less eminent persons. Most issues are never carried
beyond this ruling group; the lay publics catch only echoes of
the debate.
Lippmann did not present himself as a
moral critic of ordinary citizens. Dismissing the theory that
people were "competent to direct the course of affairs,"
he wrote: "I think it is a false idea. I do not mean an undesirable
ideal. I mean an unattainable ideal, bad only in the sense that
it is bad for a fat man to try to be a ballet dancer."
Although Dewey tried to answer Lippmann
in The Public and Its Problems, he did not deny Lippmann's anecdotal
information. He conceded that citizens were unprepared to understand
political and social issues, but he thought that they could be
made competent by educational and political reform. Lippmann and
Dewey represented two influential positions in the Progressive-Era
debate. Diehard skeptics favored professional management, doubting
the capacities of the public, while reformers hoped that more
and better schooling could produce an informed electorate.
Neither side had much hard information
with which to support its case. But during and after the Second
World War, public opinion became a subject of statistical measurement.
Polling data, George Gallup predicted, would show that "the
case against the common man has frequently proceeded on the basis
of the flimsiest circumstantial evidence." Gallup admitted
that his polls were just the "early returns," but he
was sure that further data would only confirm his faith in the
"honesty and common sense" of most citizens. Ordinary
people grasped the "broad principles" of policy and
adjusted "themselves to the ever-changing movement of events."
He was wrong. When academic researchers
began to poll people scientifically, all their results seemed
to confirm Lippmann's anecdotal evidence about public ignorance.
A group of political scientists associated with the Survey Research
Center at the University of Michigan conducted the first large-scale
longitudinal studies, from which they concluded that "the
average citizen is very much less involved in politics than is
often imagined. His awareness of political events is limited and
his concern with ideological problems is only rudimentary."
Most students of democracy had assumed
that citizens could make rational choices among policy alternatives,
and that professional leaders offered people such choices at election
time. But the Michigan researchers drew "a portrait of an
electorate almost wholly without detailed information about decision
making in government." The public, they argued, "knows
little about what government has done . . . or what the parties
propose to do. It is almost completely unable to judge the rationality
of government actions; knowing little of particular policies and
what has led to them, the mass electorate is not able to appraise
either its goals or the appropriateness of the means chosen to
serve these goals." Consequently, election results were less
meaningful than most politicians had believed, and leaders ought
to make decisions without heeding so-called public opinion.
One member of the Michigan School was
Philip E. Converse, who found that most people's opinions on given
issues did not remain stable, nor did their attitudes evolve in
response to events. Rather, a typical individual's responses over
time were "statistically random." Nevertheless, most
Americans had deep partisan loyalties. Thus, although they might
randomly change their minds about issues such as school desegregation,
they would vote reliably for one party and its candidates. This
was putting the cart before the horse, Converse thought, because
a party was supposed to be "an instrument to further particular
policy preferences."
It seemed, too, that answers to opinion
polls were extremely sensitive to the exact phrasing and ordering
of questions. As a result, pollsters struggled (with some success)
to devise questionnaires that would draw consistent and meaningful
answers. But their difficulties suggested that citizens had a
rather shallow acquaintance with important issues. If, for example,
most people had thought about school desegregation by 196O, they
wouldn't have been influenced by subtle changes in question-order.
Apparently, the Progressives' ideal of an independent and rational
voter was a fantasy.
As information about scanty public knowledge
came to light, Anthony Downs wrote a classic book explaining why
most people didn't seek more information. "In general,"
he wrote, "it is irrational to be politically well-informed."
All information had a price; even acquiring "free" news
and opinion took time, which could be used for other purposes.
Information relevant to people's work was comparatively valuable,
since it could raise their incomes. But political information
could only make their votes more intelligent. Given the large
number of people voting, this was not particularly important to
each person or to anyone else. Unless people gained pleasure or
satisfaction from acts of citizenship, it was irrational for them
to go to the polls-let alone inform themselves about candidates
and issues. Downs noted, further, that poor people had a harder
time paying the costs of information and voting, so they were
especially likely to opt out of politics. We know today that people
at the bottom of the economic ladder are distressingly ill-informed
about political matters that may directly affect them. For instance,
two out of three of the poorest Americans cannot describe the
political parties' attitudes toward government spending, whereas
most wealthy Americans know exactly how the Democrats differ from
the Republicans. This information gap helps to explain the difference
in voter participation between rich and poor, because it makes
no sense to vote if you lack information about the issues.
While members of the Michigan School were
analyzing poll data, a small group of students on the same campus
read Dewey and adopted his moral stance. The public had to become
competent, they thought, or else the transformative potential
of democracy would be wasted. In particular, the poor and dispossessed
had to participate, or else policy would continue to be set by
a satisfied bourgeoisie. These students deplored rampant apathy
and the "withdrawal from public life." For instance,
they denounced "the faceless ones polled by Gallup who listed
'international affairs' fourteenth on their list of 'problems'
but who also expected thermonuclear war in the next few years."
For them, inconsistent answers to poll questions were a source
of moral outrage.
Thus SDS was born; and soon a whole movement
aimed to bring political awareness to an apathetic public. The
radicals were not entirely unsuccessful. Individuals' opinions
became strikingly more consistent between 1960 and 1964, and they
stayed both consistent and polarized throughout the decade of
Johnson and McGovern, Goldwater and Wallace. Leaders on the extreme
right and left offered people distinct political choices, clarifying
their opinions. Participation generally rose and Americans' reported
interest in government and politics was relatively high in the
decade after 1964. Almost half the population could name their
own U.S. representatives in 1974, the highest level ever recorded.
Nevertheless, voter turnout began its
long decline in 196O, and the gains in knowledge and participation
receded during the 1970s. Today, most people do not know basic
information about the official political system, such as who represents
them in Congress or whether the Republicans are more conservative
than the Democrats. We could argue that these facts don't matter.
There is, after all, hardly any difference between the two parties,
and the names of politicians could be considered trivia. But in
practice there is usually a link between factual knowledge and
habits of deliberation. As Richard Niemi and Jane Junn write,
"One can live one's daily life without knowing that the president
is the commander-in-chief of the armed forces or, for that matter,
without knowing the name of the president. But how many political
discussions and how many news reports would be incomprehensible
without this information?"' What's more, people who do know
such facts tend to vote; and this active, informed minority is
disproportionately wealthy, educated, and white. After the 1998
election, news reports suggested that the Democrats had performed
unexpectedly well because of comparatively high turnout among
poor people (two-thirds of whom voted Democratic). But the poorest
fifth of the population still represented just 8 percent of the
electorate.
If those who participated in politics
somehow came to reflect the racial, economic, regional, and sexual
composition of the overall population, then elections would be
fair. But even if the electorate were representative, it would
still be disappointing if most Americans knew little about government
and abstained from voting. The Progressives dreamed of a national
dialogue about moral and political questions that aimed toward
consensus. Elections are opportunities for such discussion, but
if half of the population opts out of the conversation, then there
is no hope for consensus, and little reason to believe that a
truly popular opinion has formed. Nor can we assume that the people
who abstain from politics are satisfied with the status quo: they
are so poorly informed about the government's behavior that their
passive acquiescence does not signify support.
p93
We know that people who are asked to participate in politics tend
to comply, but less than half are ever asked.
p93
We could, I think: broaden political participation and knowledge
if we increased the rate of membership in voluntary associations.
Certainly there is a clear correlation between membership and
political engagement.
p95
Just talking about political issues-even in homogenous groups
and without much information-allows us to develop preferences
and values that can guide us as we vote and make decisions in
the market. Without this simplest kind of deliberation, we are
incapable of democratic citizenship, because we have no views
for the government to reflect. Therefore, simply talking (or reading
and writing) about political issues is essential. But if we only
talk to relatives or old friends, then we won't be exposed to
many new ideas and values. Talking in diverse groups is better;
it may expose us to a broader range of perspectives and make our
judgments both wiser and less selfish. Finally, a conversation
that is serious, civil, fair, and inclusive creates the potential
for consensus, which is the ideal outcome, because it renders
coercion unnecessary. This is another reason that associations
are crucial to the health of a democracy.
p97
Most people never seriously discuss the distribution of wealth,
status, and power between workers and management, professionals
and laborers, the middle class and the poor. The status quo seems
almost natural: it is part of the immutable backdrop before which
life is played. People complain about abusive employers, but mainly
because of their personal failings; and they lament general unfairness,
but much as they might deplore inclement weather. Proposals for
radical change are discussed mainly in academic circles. Average
Americans don't so much disagree with such proposals as ignore
them; for no one raises them in conversation.
More discussion of class interests would
produce more controversy. Tension always increases when leaders
like Patrick Buchanan and Jesse Jackson invoke class distinctions.
The ultimate aim of a civil society is not conflict but consensus.
As Theodore Roosevelt said in 1904, "No republic can permanently
exist when it becomes a republic of classes, where the man feels
not the interest of the whole people, but the particular class
to which he belongs, or fancies that he belongs, as being of prime
importance." Many of Roosevelt's contemporaries, including
Woodrow Wilson, also deplored class rhetoric. But Americans' general
silence about class does not reflect true consensus. What Rauschenbusch
wrote in 1907 could be said as well today: "We hear passionate
protests against the use of the word 'class' in America. There
are no classes in our country, we are told. But the hateful part
is not the word, but the thing."
Why do Americans shy away from discussions
of class? One possible reason is ideology-in particular, the widely
held view that we all belong to one economic class, although race
and gender divide us. There is no question that many Americans
believe this ideology, but that does not explain their silence
about class: we want to know why alternative views are so rarely
heard. American classes lack the self-consciousness and assertiveness
of ethnic and sexual groups.
But our lack of class-consciousness could
result from the dearth of conversation, rather than vice versa.
In any case, only 60 percent of Americans describe themselves
as "middle-class," which means that at least 40 percent
of the population acknowledges class differences.
Perhaps the underlying cause of the silence
is that true deliberation only occurs among peers, and our peers
(almost by definition) do not belong to our class. Black and white
workers, male and female colleagues are forced to listen to each
other to some degree, however biased they may be, because officially
they are equals. But employers and employees are officially unequal,
so deliberation about economic issues is almost impossible in
the workplace. If workers complain about the distribution of profit
between labor and management, they risk being fired. No one expects
the firm's ownership to try to reach consensus with its workers
on terms of equality, unless the workers happen to belong to a
strong union: now a rare circumstance. Fraternal organizations
(such as the Elks and Masons) often permitted middle-class people
and workers to talk as equals. However, their membership levels
have fallen dramatically. The shift in membership from fraternal
organizations to professional associations suggests that class
differences have worsened even as other barriers have lifted.
p99
A New Deal slogan had been: "If you want to live like a Republican,
vote Democratic." But in recent decades, many traditional
Democrats have actually begun to live as Republicans used to live
in the 1930s-in affluence-and so they have begun to vote like
Republicans. In 1993, a 41-percent plurality of adults favored
cuts in government services (and not just in spending) if this
would permit lower taxes; only 20 percent favored more services
and more taxes.
How many people we call "affluent"
depends on our definition of the word. But the median household
income-roughly $37,000 in 1997-is remarkably high by global and
historical standards. It puts more than half of the population
in the bourgeoisie, an unprecedented phenomenon. Also, three-fifths
of American families have accumulated at least $30,000 in assets;
and by the time they reach retirement age, people in this group
have saved a median of $138,000. Almost two-thirds of the population
own their own home (with median equity of almost $47,000); and
four-fifths own at least one car. About half of the rising generation
is educated beyond high school. Nevertheless, some Americans remain
in poverty, and the actual quality of life of the urban poor may
have declined since World War II. ,~ According to John Kenneth
Galbraith, the activist government of the New Deal and the Great
Society seemed at first to be a "permanent revolution."
But in reality, the welfare state was "a self-liquidating
political movement." He writes:
With the spread of well-being, more and
more people have a comfortable satisfaction with their own economic
position. Once thus blessed, they find, as in all past times,
a suitably persuasive reason for separating themselves and their
consciences from the still-persisting poverty of the now less
numerous poor.... Those who are financially secure are the people
who are most likely to vote in elections and who are best able
to contribute to the high cost, especially in the United States,
of modern political campaigns. So endowed, they vote out of power
those who made the revolution on behalf of the insecure and the
poor and who would continue efforts on behalf of the smaller number
of the underprivileged who remain.
The health-care crisis illustrates Galbraith's
thesis. In 1991, with health-care reform rising quickly on the
national agenda, 66 percent of Americans still rated their own
health insurance as "excellent" or "good."
And on the eve of President Clinton's announcement of a health-reform
package in 1993, polls showed that more than 80 percent of adults
were satisfied with their own medical benefits and services. These
people could not be expected to support national health insurance
with much enthusiasm, unless it somehow brought them lower health
bills. Forty-three million uninsured people constitute a vast
human tragedy, perhaps the worst social disaster in the developed
world; but uninsured people do not cast very many votes in a nation
of 250 million. Most people with family incomes under $3O,000
predicted that the Clinton plan would make health care better,
while wealthier people thought that it would make things worse.
But only one-third of voters belonged to the under-$30,000 income
category. Thus a majority of American voters may have been basically
happy when health-care reform stopped at the point it had reached
in 1968: with Medicare for the elderly (because everyone gets
old), Medicaid to provide minimal support for the very poor, and
$65 billion a year in tax deductions for middle- and upper-income
taxpayers who buy their own health insurance.
In general, the existing balance of power
has prevented most kinds of social intervention, including the
establishment of a public health-care system or any aggressive
action against unemployment, poverty, or homelessness. However,
government action has been possible in restricted areas. For example,
86.3 percent of all American families own a car, but none can
afford their own highways. Federal aid for road construction has
therefore remained popular, although support for mass transportation-which
is used by a generally poor minority-has been weak. And most Americans
remain committed to public higher education, because private universities
are so expensive that only a wealthy minority can afford them
without subsidy. But most people are not interested in redistributing
funds to poor public school districts; they would rather raise
funds for their schools within their own communities, where everyone
usually enjoys a similar income level. For example, a proposed
Texas amendment to force wealthy school districts to share funds
with poor ones was defeated in a 1993 referendum, two-to-one.
Opinions in favor of redistribution have
consistently correlated with income. For example, a 1939 Roper
poll asked: "Do you think our government should or should
not redistribute wealth by heavy taxes on the rich?" Thirty-four
percent more poor people than "prosperous" people said
yes. The same kind of correlation has shown up in polls ever since.
Many middle-class Americans have generous feelings toward their
less-fortunate compatriots, but they express these feelings at
the donation box, not the ballot box. A government cannot survive
for long as a charity, spending taxpayers' money on purely altruistic
goals, if only because private, nonprofit organizations are better
equipped to fulfill people's charitable priorities. Therefore,
a population with a middle-class majority will probably lack widespread
support for income redistribution.
In a host of suburban communities across
the country, people essentially get what they pay for from local
government-little more, little less. In an economically homogeneous
area, such as the typical suburb (where a majority of voters now
lives), everyone pays a roughly equal share of the cost of police
protection, schools, and roadworks, and everyone benefits from
these amenities to a roughly equal degree." There are few
free-riders, because the poor are safely closeted away across
political boundaries in the inner cities or countryside. In a
few suburbs, all children are excluded by zoning laws, thereby
obviating the need for any school taxes. On the other hand, the
people who live in this kind of community get less than they pay
for from federal domestic programs, because the beneficiaries
of health, employment, and welfare programs have less-than-average
incomes. Therefore, middle-class suburbanites no longer need or
want many traditional kinds of federal programs.
p101
To be severely harmed by a majority of one's fellow citizens is
hardly better than being oppressed by a despot.
p101
... a sin of omission by the government is little better than
a sin of commission. Progressives do not accept the naturalness
of market outcomes; for them, only democracy is sovereign. A truly
democratic society must examine itself critically, not tolerating
some people's suffering just because the market has caused it.
To refuse to provide medical care for poor workers is a serious
moral omission, since we can clearly afford universal insurance.
Wealthy Americans should not be bullied (any more than poor ones),
but they should have to negotiate a mutually acceptable arrangement
with the less advantaged. Instead, they dominate the electoral
process and hardly care what the minority thinks.
Progressives should also object to antigovernment
policies because they reflect a general retreat from the public
sphere. Citizens are free to decide how big the private and public
sectors should be. There is nothing in Progressivism that requires
intrusive government or high taxes. But beyond a certain point,
the decision to solve problems privately is harmful to democracy.
Consider, for example, `[ the current fashion for gated communities,
malls with private security forces, and professional guards for
homes and offices. By hiring a security service and posting its
logo on our front lawn, we hope that we can persuade criminals
to stay away-even if that means that they will rob someone else
who lacks such protection. At the same time, many of us withdraw
our financial support from the city and state governments that
provide general law enforcement, education, and employment programs.
As a result, we may no longer deliberate together about an issue
that has traditionally been considered public: crime and punishment.
The scope of civil society and democratic government has narrowed
frighteningly. Civilization itself implies joint action against
violence; taking care of one's own s the law of the jungle
The
New Progressive Era
Index
of Website
Home Page