Adjusting the Poor
excerpted from the book
When Corporations Rule the World
by David C. Korten
published by Kumarian Press, 1995
In the flurry of global institution building that followed
World War II, the spotlight of public attention was focused on
the United Nations (UN), which was to be inclusive of all countries,
each with an equal voice- at least in its General Assembly. Delegates
to the UN are public figures, and debates are open to public view
and often heated. Yet the General Assembly has little real power.
The real ability to act is vested in the Security Council, in
which each of the major powers maintains the right of veto. Judging
from its governance structures, it must be concluded that the
UN was created primarily to function as a forum for debate.
In contrast, three other multilateral institutions were created
with relatively little fanfare to operate outside the public eye-the
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (commonly
known as the World Bank), the International Monetary Fund (IMF),
and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). These three
agencies are commonly referred to as the Bretton Woods institutions,
in tribute to a meeting of representatives of forty-four nations
who gathered in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, July 1 - 22, 1944,
to reach agreement on an institutional framework for the post-World
War II global economy. The public purpose of what became known
as the Bretton Woods system was to unite the world in a web of
economic prosperity and interdependence that would preclude nations'
taking up arms. Another purpose in the eyes of its architects
was to create an open world economy unified under U.S. leadership
that would ensure unchallenged U.S. access to the world's markets
and raw materials. Two of the Bretton Woods institutions- the
IMF and the World Bank-were actually created at the Bretton Woods
meeting. The GATT was created at a subsequent international meeting.
Although formally designated as "special agencies"
of the UN, the Bretton Woods institutions function nearly autonomously
from it Their governance and administrative processes are secret-carefully
shielded from public scrutiny and democratic debate. Indeed, the
internal operating processes of the World Bank are so secretive
that access to many of its most important documents relating to
country plans, strategies, and priorities is denied to even its
own governing executive directors. In the World Bank and the IMF,
the big national powers have both veto power over certain decisions
and voting shares in proportion to their shares of the subscribed
capital-ensuring their ability to set and control the agenda.
*****
In their roles as international debt collectors, the World
Bank and the IMF have become increasingly intrusive in dictating
the public policies of indebted countries and undermining progress
toward democratic governance and public accountability. As Jonathan
Cahn argues in the Harvard Human Rights Journal:
"The World Bank must be regarded as a governance institution,
exercising power through its financial leverage to legislate entire
legal regimens and even to alter the constitutional structure
of borrowing nations. Bank-approved consultants often rewrite
a country's trade policy, fiscal policies, civil service requirements,
labor laws, health care arrangements, environmental regulations,
energy policy, resettlement requirements, procurement rules, and
budgetary policy." In its governance role, the World Bank-a
global bureaucracy-is making decisions for people to whom it is
not accountable that would normally be the responsibility of elected
legislative bodies. The very process of the borrowing that created
the indebtedness that gave the World Bank and the IMF the power
to dictate the policies of borrowing countries represented an
egregious assault on the principles of democratic accountability.
Loan agreements, whether with the World Bank, the IMF, other official
lending institutions, or commercial banks, are routinely negotiated
in secret between banking officials and a handful of government
officials-who in many instances are themselves unelected and unaccountable
to the people on whose behalf they are obligating the national
treasury to foreign lenders. Even in democracies, the borrowing
procedures generally bypass the normal appropriation processes
of democratically elected legislative bodies. Thus, government
agencies are able to increase their own budgets without legislative
approval, even though the legislative body will have to come up
with the revenues to cover repayment. Foreign loans also enable
governments to increase current expenditures without the need
to raise current taxes-a feature that is especially popular with
wealthy decision makers. The same officials who approve the loans
often benefit directly through participation in contracts and
"commissions" from grateful contractors. The system
creates a powerful incentive to over borrow.
In effect, those officials who sign foreign loan agreements
are obligating the people of the country to future financial obligations
completely outside of any process of public review and consent.
This becomes especially egregious when, as has happened to millions
of people in Bank client countries, the loan-funded projects displace
the poor from homes and lands, pollute their waters, cut down
their forests, and destroy their fisheries. Then, adding insult
to injury, when the bills come due, the poor are told that their
social services and wages l must be cut to repay the country's
loan obligations.
The Corporate Connection
Although it seeks to create an image of serving the poor and
their borrowing governments, the World Bank is primarily a creature
of the transnational financial system. The Bank's direct financial
links to the transnational corporate sector on both the borrowing
and the lending ends of its operation have received far too little
attention. Technically, the Bank is owned by its member governments,
which contribute its paid-in capital; this was only $10.53 billion,
as of 1993. In addition member governments have pledged $155 billion
that can be called by
the Bank if needed to meet its financial obligations. The
paid-in capital and the pledges are not actually loaned out. They
secure the Bank's extensive borrowing operations in the international
financial markets, where it raises the funds that are then re-lent
to governments at more favorable rates than they could obtain
by borrowing directly.
Although the Bank lends to governments, its projects normally
involve large procurement contracts with transnational construction
firms, large consulting firms, and procurement contractors. These
firms are one of the Bank's most powerful political constituencies.
The area of Bank operations that is watched most closely by the
Bank's executive directors-representatives of its shareholder
governments- is the procurement process. Each director wants to
ensure that the countries he or she represents are getting at
least their fair share of procurement contracts. The U.S. Treasury
Department is quite up front in its appeals to the corporate interest
in supporting funding replenishments for the Bank. Treasury officials
point out that for every $1 the U.S. government contributes to
the World Bank, more than $2 comes back to U.S. exporters in procurement
contracts. As Treasury Secretary Lloyd Bentsen assured Congress
in 1994, "The dollars we have sent abroad through the development
banks come back home in increased U.S. exports and more U.S. jobs."
The sole function of one arm of the World Bank, the International
Finance Corporation, is to make government-guaranteed loans on
favorable terms to private investors whose projects are too risky
to qualify for commercial bank financing. It accounts for 10 to
12 percent of total World Bank lending. The potentials for abuse
are even greater than with the Bank's core lending programs. To
date, the Bank has kept the International Finance Corporation
so far out of the public eye that it is seldom mentioned, even
by Bank critics. However, given its own ideological belief in
free-market forces, it seems difficult for the Bank to justify
a major operation devoted to using publicly guaranteed funds to
finance large private ventures that are so risky that commercial
banks will not fund them.
If the Poor Mattered
When the formation of the World Bank was proposed, Republican
Senator Robert Taft emerged as a formidable opponent. His argument,
made in 1945, reveals a significant insight into why foreign aid
based on large financial flows is a deeply flawed idea:
"I think we overestimate the value of American money
and American aid to other nations. No people can make over another
people. Every nation must solve its own problems, and whatever
we do can only be of slight assistance to help it over its most
severe problems.... A nation that comes to rely on gifts and loans
from others is too likely to postpone the essential, tough measures
necessary for its own salvation.
Taft maintained that the major beneficiaries would be Wall
Street investment bankers: "it is almost a subsidy to the
business of investment bankers, and will also undoubtedly increase
the business to be done by the larger banks. Subsequent events
have substantially affirmed Taft's argument.
Properly understood, development is a process by which people
increase their human, institutional, and technical capacities
to produce the goods and services needed to achieve sustainable
improvements in their quality of life using the resources available
to them. Many of us call such a process people-centered development-not
only because it benefits people but also because it is centered
in people. It is especially important to involve the poor and
excluded, thus allowing them to meet their own needs through their
own productive efforts. A small amount of help from abroad can
be very useful in a people-centered development process, but too
much foreign funding can prevent real development and even break
down the existing capabilities of a people to sustain themselves.
Debates about import-substitution versus export-led development
rarely acknowledge the people-centered alternative. Both start
from the top, focusing on the production of more of the things
that people who are already well-off want to buy. Poor people
seldom buy imported goods. Their needs are met by simple locally
produced goods. When a country seeks to replace imports with domestic
production, it usually means producing at home more of the goods
that those who are relatively well-off buy from abroad. When a
country seeks to increase its exports, it generally means gearing
domestic productive capability to producing things for relatively
well-off foreigners. In theory, either strategy will produce more
jobs for poor people so that they can participate m the money
economy. But usually the jobs these strategies provide are too
few and too poorly compensated to eliminate poverty. Either strategy
can, and in all too many instances does, displace local production
of the things that poor people use in order to produce more of
the things that wealthier people want-even depriving the poor
of their basic means of livelihood, such as when the lands of
small farmers are taken over by estates producing for export.
Let's reduce the problem to its basics. Poverty-generally
defined as a lack of adequate money-is not the issue. It is the
deprivation associated with a lack of money that is the problem-the
lack of access to adequate food, clothing, shelter, and other
essentials of a decent life. This simple fact suggests a people-centered
alternative to both the import-substitution and export-led development
models: pursuing policies that create opportunities for people
who are experiencing deprivation to produce the things that they
need to have a better life.
This is, in many respects, what Japan, Korea, and Taiwan did.
Each made significant investments to achieve a high level of adult
literacy and basic education, carried out radical land reform
to create a thriving rural economy based on small farm production,
and supported the development of rural industries that produced
things needed by small farm families. These became the foundation
of larger industries. The development of these countries was equity-led,
not export-led- contrary to the historical revisionism of corporate
libertarians. Only after these countries had developed broad-based
domestic economies did they become major exporters in the international
economy.
From the standpoint of transnational corporate capital and
the World Bank, a people-centered development strategy presents
a major problem. Since it creates very little demand for imports,
it also creates little demand for foreign loans. Furthermore,
it favors local ownership of assets and thus provides few profit
opportunities for transnational corporations.
*****
If measured by contributions to improving the lives of people
or strengthening the institutions of democratic governance, the
World Bank and the IMF have been disastrous failures-imposing
an enormous burden on the world's poor and seriously impeding
their development. In terms of fulfilling the mandates set for
them by their original architects-advancing economic globalization
under the domination of the economically powerful-they both have
been a resounding success. In addition, the IMF was highly successful
in averting, at least temporarily, a global financial crisis on
terms favorable to the Northern commercial banks. Together, the
Bank and the IMF have helped build powerful political constituencies
aligned with corporate libertarianism, weakened the democratic
accountability of Southern governments, usurped the functions
of democratically elected officials, and removed most consequential
legal and institutional barriers to the recolonization of Southern
economies by transnational capital. They have arguably done more
harm to more people than any other pair of nonmilitary institutions
in human history.
When
Corporations Rule the World