How to democratize American democracy
by Arhur Schlesinger, Jr.
/authors/schlesinger-a.html
The true significance of the disputed 2000 election has thus
far escaped public attention. This was an election that elevated
the popular-vote loser to the American presidency. But that astounding
fact has been obscured: first by the flood of electoral complaints
about deceptive ballots, hanging chads, and so on in Florida;
then by the political astuteness of the court-appointed president
in behaving as if he had won the White House by a landslide; and
now by the effect of September 11 in presidentializing George
W. Bush and giving him commanding popularity in the polls.
"The fundamental maxim of republican government,"
observed Alexander Hamilton in the 22d Federalist, "requires
that the sense of the majority should prevail." A reasonable
deduction from Hamilton's premise is that the presidential candidate
who wins the most votes in an election should also win the election.
That quite the opposite can happen is surely the great anomaly
in the American democratic order.
Yet the National Commission on Federal Election Reform, a
body appointed in the wake of the 2000 election and co-chaired
(honorarily) by former Presidents Gerald Ford and Jimmy Carter,
virtually ignored it. Last August, in a report optimistically
entitled To Assure Pride and Confidence in the Electoral Process,
the commission concluded that it had satisfactorily addressed
"most of the problems that came into national view"
in 2000. But nothing in the ponderous 80-page document addressed
the most fundamental problem that came into national view: the
constitutional anomaly that permits the people's choice to be
refused the presidency.
Little consumed more time during our nation's Constitutional
Convention than debate over the mode of choosing the chief executive.
The framers, determined to ensure the separation of powers, rejected
the proposal that Congress elect the president. Both James Madison
and James Wilson, the "fathers" of the Constitution,
argued for direct election by the people, but the convention,
fearing the parochialism of uninformed voters, also rejected that
plan. In the end, the framers agreed on the novel device of an
electoral college. Each state would appoint electors equal in
number to its representation in Congress. The electors would then
vote for two persons. The one receiving a majority of electoral
votes would then become president; the runner-up, vice president.
And in a key sentence, the Constitution stipulated that of these
two persons at least one should not be from the same state as
the electors.
The convention expected the electors to be cosmopolitans who
would know, or know of, eminences in other states. But this does
not mean that they were created as free agents authorized to routinely
ignore or invalidate the choice of the voters. The electors, said
John Clopton of Virginia are the "organs . . . acting from
a certain and unquestioned knowledge of the choice of the people,
by whom they themselves were appointed, and under immediate responsibility
to them."
Madison summed it up when the convention finally adopted the
electoral college: "The president is now to be elected by
the people." The president, he assured the Virginia ratifying
convention, would be "the choice of the people at large."
In the First Congress, he described the president as appointed
"by the suffrage of three million people."
"It was desirable," Alexander Hamilton wrote in
the 68th Federalist, "that the sense of the people should
operate in the choice of the person to whom so important a trust
was to be confided." As Lucius Wilmerding, Jr., concluded
in his magistral study of the electoral college: "The Electors
were never meant to choose the President but only to pronounce
the votes of the people."
Even with such a limited function, however, the electoral
college has shaped the contours of American politics and thus
captured the attention of politicians. With the ratification of
the 12th Amendment in 1804, electors were required to vote separately
for president and vice president, a change that virtually guaranteed
that both would be of the same party. Though unknown to the Constitution
and deplored by the framers, political parties were remolding
presidential elections. By 1836 all the states except South Carolina
had decided to cast their votes as a unit -- winner take all,
no matter how narrow the margin. This decision minimized the power
of third parties and created a solid foundation for a two-party
system.
"The mode of appointment of the Chief Magistrate [President]
of the United States," wrote Hamilton in the 68th Federalist
"is almost the only part of the system, of any consequence,
which has escaped without severe censure." This may have
been true when Hamilton wrote in 1788; it was definitely not true
thereafter. According to the Congressional Research Service, legislators
since the First Congress have offered more than a thousand proposals
to alter the mode of choosing presidents.
No legislator has advocated the election of the president
by Congress. Some have advocated modifications in the electoral
college -- to change the electoral units from states to congressional
districts, for example, or to require a proportional division
of electoral votes. In the 1950s, the latter approach received
considerable congressional favor in a plan proposed by Senator
Henry Cabot Lodge, Jr., and Representative Ed Gossett. The Lodge-Gossett
amendment would have ended the winner-take-all electoral system
and divided each state's electoral vote according to the popular
vote. In 1950 the Senate endorsed the amendment, but the House
turned it down. Five years later, Senator Estes Kefauver revived
the Lodge-Gossett plan and won the backing of the Senate Judiciary
Committee. A thoughtful debate ensued with Senators John F. Kennedy
and Paul H. Douglas leading the opposition and defeating the amendment.
Neither the district plan nor the proportionate plan would
prevent a popular- vote loser from winning the White House. To
correct this great anomaly of the Constitution, many have advocated
the abolition of the electoral college and its replacement by
direct popular elections.
The first "minority" president was John Quincy Adams.
In the 1824 election, Andrew Jackson led in both popular and electoral
votes; but with four candidates dividing the electoral vote, he
failed to win an electoral-college majority. The Constitution
provides that if no candidate has a majority, the House of Representatives
must choose among the top three. Speaker of the House Henry Clay,
who came in fourth, threw his support to Adams, thereby making
him president. When Adams then made Clay his secretary of state,
Jacksonian cries of "corrupt bargain" filled the air
for the next four years and helped Jackson win the electoral majority
in 1828.
"To the people belongs the right of electing their Chief
Magistrate," Jackson told Congress in 1829. "The first
principle of our system," he said, is "that the majority
is to govern." He asked for the removal of all "intermediate"
agencies preventing a "fair expression of the will of the
majority." And in a tacit verdict on Adams's failed administration,
Jackson added: "A President elected by a minority can not
enjoy the confidence necessary to the successful discharge of
his duties."
History bears out Jackson's point. The next two minority presidents
-- Rutherford B. Hayes in 1877 and Benjamin Harrison in 1889 --
had, like Adams, ineffectual administrations. All suffered setbacks
in their midterm congressional elections. None won a second term
in the White House.
The most recent president to propose a direct-election amendment
was Jimmy Carter in 1997. The amendment, he said, would "ensure
that the candidate chosen by the votes actually becomes President.
Under the Electoral College, it is always possible that the winner
of the popular vote will not be elected." This had already
happened, Carter said, in 1824, 1876, and 1888.
Actually, Carter placed too much blame on the electoral system.
Neither J.Q. Adams in 1824 nor Hayes in 1876 owed his elevation
to the electoral college. The House of Representatives, as noted,
elected Adams. Hayes's anointment was more complicated.
In 1876, Samuel J. Tilden, the Democratic candidate, won the
popular vote, and it appeared that he had won the electoral vote
too. But the Confederate states were still under military occupation,
and electoral boards in Florida, Louisiana, and South Carolina
disqualified enough Democratic ballots to give Hayes, the Republican
candidate, the electoral majority.
The Republicans controlled the Senate; the Democrats, the
House. Which body would count the electoral votes? To resolve
the deadlock, Congress appointed an electoral commission. By an
8-7 party-line vote, the commission gave all the disputed votes
to Hayes. This was a supreme election swindle. But it was the
rigged electoral commission, not the electoral college, that denied
the popular-vote winner the presidency.
In 1888 the electoral college did deprive the popular-vote
winner, Democrat Grover Cleveland, of victory. But 1888 was a
clouded election. Neither candidate received a majority, and Cleveland's
margin was only 95,000 votes. Moreover, the claim was made, and
was widely accepted at the time and by scholars since, that white
election officials in the South banned perhaps 300,000 black Republicans
from the polls. The installation of a minority president in 1889
took place without serious protest.
The Republic later went through several other elections in
which a small shift of votes would have given the popular-vote
loser an electoral-college victory. In 1916, if Charles Evans
Hughes had gained 4,000 votes in California, he would have won
the electoral-college majority, through he lost the popular vote
to Woodrow Wilson by more than half a million. In 1948, a shift
of fewer than 30,000 votes in three states would have given Thomas
E. Dewey the electoral-college majority, though he ran more than
two million votes behind Harry Truman. In 1976, a shift of 8,000
votes in two states would have kept President Gerald Ford in office,
though he ran more than a million and a half votes behind Jimmy
Carter.
Over the last half-century, many other eminent politicos and
organizations have also advocated direct popular elections: Presidents
Richard Nixon and Gerald Ford; Vice Presidents Alben Barkley and
Hubert Humphrey; Senators Robert A. Taft, Mike Mansfield, Edward
Kennedy, Henry Jackson, Robert Dole, Howard Baker, and Everett
Dirksen; the American Bar Association, the League of Women Voters,
the AFL-CIO, and the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. Polls have shown
overwhelming public support for direct elections.
In the late 1960s, the drive for a direct-election amendment
achieved a certain momentum. Led by Senator Birch Bayh of Indiana,
an inveterate and persuasive constitutional reformer, the campaign
was fueled by the fear that Governor George Wallace of Alabama
might win enough electoral votes in 1968 to throw the election
into the House of Representatives. In May 1968, a Gallup poll
recorded 66 percent of the U.S. public in favor of direct election
-- and in November of that year, an astonishing 80 percent. But
Wallace's 46 electoral votes in 1968 were not enough to deny Nixon
a majority, and complacency soon took over. "The decline
in one-party states," a Brookings Institution study concluded
in 1970, "has made it far less likely today that the runner-up
in popular votes will be elected President."
Because the danger of electoral-college misfire seemed academic,
abolition of the electoral college again became a low-priority
issue. Each state retained the constitutional right to appoint
its electors "in such manner as the legislature thereof directs."
And all but two states, Maine and Nebraska, kept the unit rule.
Then came the election of 2000. For the fourth time in American
history, the winner of the popular vote was refused the presidency.
And Albert Gore, Jr., had won the popular vote, not by Grover
Cleveland's dubious 95,000 but by more than half a million. Another
nearly three million votes had gone to the third-party candidate
Ralph Nader, making the victor George W. Bush more than ever a
minority president.
Nor was Bush's victory in the electoral college unclouded
by doubt. The electoral vote turned on a single state, Florida.
Five members of the Supreme Court, forsaking their usual deference
to state sovereignty, stopped the Florida recount and thereby
made Bush president. Critics wondered: If the facts had been the
same but the candidates reversed, with Bush winning the popular
vote (as indeed observers had rather expected) and Gore hoping
to win the electoral vote, would the gang of five have found the
same legal arguments to elect Gore that they used to elect Bush?
I expected an explosion of public outrage over the rejection
of the people's choice. But there was surprisingly little in the
way of outcry. It is hard to image such acquiescence in a popular-vote-loser
presidency if the popular- vote winner had been, say, Adlai Stevenson
or John F. Kennedy or Ronald Reagan. Such leaders attracted do-or-die
supporters, voters who cared intensely about them and who not
only would have questioned the result but would have been ardent
in pursuit of fundamental reform. After a disappointing campaign,
Vice President Gore simply did not excite the same impassioned
commitment.
Yet surely the 2000 election put the Republic in an intolerable
predicament -- intolerable because the result contravened the
theory of democracy. Many expected that the election would resurrect
the movement for direct election of presidents. Since direct elections
have obvious democratic plausibility and since few Americans understand
the electoral college anyway, its abolition seems a logical remedy.
The resurrection has not taken place. Constitutional reformers
seem intimidated by the argument that the direct-election amendment
would antagonize small-population states and therefore could not
be ratified. It would necessarily eliminate the special advantage
conferred on small states by the two electoral votes handed to
all states regardless of population. Small- state opposition,
it is claimed, would make it impossible to collect the two- thirds
of Congress and the three-fourths of the states required for ratification.
This is an odd argument, because most political analysts are
convinced that the electoral college in fact benefits large states,
not small ones. Far from being hurt by direct elections, small
states, they say, would benefit from them. The idea that "the
present electoral-college preserves the power of the small states,"
write Lawrence D. Longley and Alan G. Braun in The Politics of
Electoral Reform, ". . . simply is not the case." The
electoral-college system "benefits large states, urban interests,
white minorities, and/or black voters." So, too, a Brookings
Institution report: "For several decades liberal, urban Democrats
and progressive, urban-suburban Republicans have tended to dominate
presidential politics; they would lose influence under the direct-vote
plan."
Racial minorities holding the balance of power in large states
agree. "Take away the electoral college," said Vernon
Jordan as president of the Urban League, "and the importance
of being black melts away. Blacks, instead of being crucial to
victory in major states, simply become 10 percent of the electorate,
with reduced impact."
The debate over whom direct elections would benefit has been
long, wearisome, contradictory, and inconclusive. Even computer
calculations are of limited use, since they assume a static political
culture. They do not take into account, nor can they predict,
the changes wrought in voter dynamics by candidates, issues, and
events.
As Senator John Kennedy said during the Lodge-Gossett debate:
"It is not only the unit vote for the Presidency we are talking
about, but a whole solar system of governmental power. If it is
proposed to change the balance of power of one of the elements
of the solar system," Kennedy observed, "it is necessary
to consider all the others. . . . What the effects of these various
changes will be on the Federal system, the two-party system, the
popular plurality system and the large-State-small-State checks
and balances system, no one knows."
Direct elections do, however, have the merit of correcting
the great anomaly of the Constitution and providing an escape
from the intolerable predicament. "The electoral college
method of electing a President of the United States," said
the American Bar Association when an amendment was last seriously
considered, "is archaic, undemocratic, complex, ambiguous,
indirect, and dangerous." In contrast, as Birch Bayh put
it, "direct popular election of the president is the only
system that is truly democratic, truly equitable, and can truly
reflect the will of the people."
The direct-election plan meets the moral criteria of a democracy.
It would elect the people's choice. It would ensure equal treatment
of all votes. It would reduce the power of sectionalism in politics.
It would reinvigorate party competition and combat voter apathy
by giving parties the incentive to get out their votes in states
that they have no hope of carrying.
The arguments for abolishing the electoral college are indeed
powerful. But direct elections raise troubling problems of their
own -- especially their impact on the two-party system and on
JFK's "solar system of governmental power."
In the nineteenth century, American parties inspired visiting
Europeans with awe. Alexis de Toqueville, in the 1830s, thought
politics "the only pleasure which an American knows."
James Bryce, half a century later, was impressed by the "military
discipline" of the parties. Voting statistics justified transatlantic
admiration. In no presidential election between the Civil War
and the end of the century did turnout fall below 70 percent of
eligible voters.
The dutiful citizens of these high-turnout years did not rush
to the polls out of uncontrollable excitement over the choices
they were about to make. The dreary procession of presidential
candidates moved Bryce to write his famous chapter in The American
Commonwealth titled "Why Great Men Are Not Chosen Presidents."
But the party was supremely effective as an agency of voter mobilization.
Party loyalty was intense. People were as likely to switch parties
as they were to switch churches. The great difference between
then and now is the decay of the party as the organizing unit
of American politics.
The modern history of parties has been the steady loss of
the functions that gave them their classical role. Civil-service
reform largely dried up the reservoir of patronage. Social legislation
reduced the need for parties to succor the poor and helpless.
Mass entertainment gave people more agreeable diversions than
listening to political harangues. Party loyalty became tenuous;
party identification, casual. Franklin D. Roosevelt observed in
1940: "The growing independence of voters, after all, has
been proved by the votes in every presidential election since
my childhood -- and the tendency, frankly, is on the increase."
Since FDR's day, a fundamental transformation in the political
environment has further undermined the shaky structure of American
politics. Two electronic technologies -- television and computerized
polling -- have had a devastating impact on the party system.
The old system had three tiers: the politician at one end, the
voter at the other, and the party in between. The party's function
was to negotiate between the politician and the voter, interpreting
each to the other and providing the links that held the political
process together.
The electronic revolution has substantially abolished this
mediating role. Television presents politicians directly to the
voters, who judge candidates far more on what the box shows them
than on what the party organization tells them. Computerized polls
present voters directly to the politicians, who judge the electorate
far more on what the polls show them than on what the party organization
tells them. The political party is left to wither on the vine.
The last half-century has been notable for the decrease in
party identification, for the increase in independent voting,
and for the number of independent presidential candidacies by
fugitives from the major parties: Henry Wallace and Strom Thurmond
in 1948, George Wallace in 1968, Eugene McCarthy in 1976, John
Anderson in 1980, Ross Perot in 1992 and 1996, and Ralph Nader
and Pat Buchanan in 2000.
The two-party system has been a source of stability; FDR called
it "one of the greatest methods of unification and of teaching
people to think in common terms." The alternative is a slow,
agonized descent into an era of what Walter Dean Burnham has termed
"politics without parties." Political adventurers might
roam the countryside like Chinese warlords, building personal
armies equipped with electronic technologies, conducting hostilities
against various rival warlords, forming alliances with others,
and, if they win elections, striving to govern through ad hoc
coalitions. Accountability would fade away. Without the stabilizing
influences of parties, American politics would grow angrier, wilder,
and more irresponsible.
There are compelling reasons to believe that the abolition
of state-by-state, winner-take-all electoral votes would hasten
the disintegration of the party system. Minor parties have a dim
future in the electoral college. Unless third parties have a solid
regional base, like the Populists of 1892 or the Dixiecrats of
1948, they cannot hope to win electoral votes. Millard Fillmore,
the Know- Nothing candidate in 1856, won 21.6 percent of the popular
vote and only 2 percent of the electoral vote. In 1912, when Theodore
Roosevelt's candidacy turned the Republicans into a third party,
William Howard Taft carried 23 percent of the popular vote and
only 1.5 percent of the electoral votes.
But direct elections, by enabling minor parties to accumulate
votes from state to state -- impossible in the electoral-college
system -- would give them a new role and a new influence. Direct-election
advocates recognize that the proliferation of minor candidates
and parties would drain votes away from the major parties. The
direct-election amendment therefore provides that if no candidate
receives 40 percent of the vote the two top candidates would fight
it out in a runoff election.
This procedure would offer potent incentives for radical zealots
(Ralph Nader, for example), freelance media adventurers (Pat Buchanan),
eccentric billionaires (Ross Perot), and flamboyant characters
(Jesse Ventura) to jump into presidential contests; incentives,
too, to "green" parties, senior-citizen parties, nativist
parties, right-to-life parties, pro-choice parties, anti-gun-
control parties, homosexual parties, prohibition parties, and
so on down the single-issue line.
Splinter parties would multiply not because they expected
to win elections but because their accumulated vote would increase
their bargaining power in the runoff. Their multiplication might
well make runoffs the rule rather than the exception. And think
of the finagling that would take place between the first and second
rounds of a presidential election! Like J.Q. Adams in 1824, the
victors would very likely find that they are a new target for
"corrupt bargains."
Direct election would very likely bring to the White House
candidates who do not get anywhere near a majority of the popular
votes. The prospect would be a succession of 41 percent presidents
or else a succession of double national elections. Moreover, the
winner in the first round might often be beaten in the second
round, depending on the deals the runoff candidates made with
the splinter parties. This result would hardly strengthen the
sense of legitimacy that the presidential election is supposed
to provide. And I have yet to mention the problem, in close elections,
of organizing a nationwide recount.
In short, direct elections promise a murky political future.
They would further weaken the party system and further destabilize
American politics. They would cure the intolerable predicament
-- but the cure might be worse than the disease.
Are we therefore stuck with the great anomaly of the Constitution?
Is no remedy possible?
There is a simple and effective way to avoid the troubles
promised by the direct-election plan and at the same time to prevent
the popular-vote loser from being the electoral-vote winner: Keep
the electoral college but award the popular-vote winner a bonus
of electoral votes. This is the "national bonus" plan
proposed in 1978 by the Twentieth Century Fund Task Force on Reform
of the Presidential Election Process. The task force included,
among others, Richard Rovere and Jeanne Kirkpatrick. (And I must
declare an interest: I was a member, too, and first proposed the
bonus plan in The Wall Street Journal in 1977.)
Under the bonus plan, a national pool of 102 new electoral
votes -- two for each state and the District of Columbia -- would
be awarded to the winner of the popular vote. This national bonus
would balance the existing state bonus -- the two electoral votes
already conferred by the Constitution on each state regardless
of population. This reform would virtually guarantee that the
popular-vote winner would also be the electoral-vote winner.
At the same time, by retaining state electoral votes and the
unit rule, the plan would preserve both the constitutional and
practical role of the states in presidential elections. By insulating
recounts, it would simplify the consequences of close elections.
By discouraging multiplication of parties and candidates, the
plan would protect the two-party system. By encouraging parties
to maximize their vote in states that they have no chance of winning,
it would reinvigorate state parties, stimulate turnout, and enhance
voter equality. The national-bonus plan combines the advantages
in the historic system with the assurance that the winner of the
popular vote will win the election, and thus it would contribute
to the vitality of federalism.
The national-bonus plan is a basic but a contained reform.
It would fit comfortably into the historic structure. It would
vindicate "the fundamental maxim of republican government
. . . that the sense of the majority should prevail." It
would make the American democracy live up to its democratic pretensions.
How many popular-vote losers will we have to send to the White
House before we finally democratize American democracy?
Political
Reform page
Index
of Website
Home
Page